stratechery.com Open in urlscan Pro
199.16.173.162  Public Scan

Submitted URL: http://www.stratechery.com/
Effective URL: https://stratechery.com/
Submission: On August 27 via api from US — Scanned from DE

Form analysis 2 forms found in the DOM

GET https://stratechery.com/

<form role="search" method="get" class="search-form" action="https://stratechery.com/">
  <label>
    <span class="screen-reader-text">Search for:</span>
    <input type="search" class="search-field aa-input" placeholder="Search …" value="" name="s" autocomplete="off" spellcheck="false" role="combobox" aria-autocomplete="list" aria-expanded="false" aria-owns="algolia-autocomplete-listbox-0" dir="auto"
      style="">
    <pre aria-hidden="true"
      style="position: absolute; visibility: hidden; white-space: pre; font-family: freight-sans-pro, Arial; font-size: 18px; font-style: normal; font-variant: normal; font-weight: 400; word-spacing: 0px; letter-spacing: normal; text-indent: 0px; text-rendering: auto; text-transform: none;"></pre>
  </label>
  <input type="submit" class="search-submit" value="Search">
</form>

GET https://stratechery.com/

<form role="search" method="get" class="search-form" action="https://stratechery.com/">
  <label>
    <span class="screen-reader-text">Search for:</span>
    <input type="search" class="search-field aa-input" placeholder="Search …" value="" name="s" autocomplete="off" spellcheck="false" role="combobox" aria-autocomplete="list" aria-expanded="false" aria-owns="algolia-autocomplete-listbox-5" dir="auto"
      style="">
    <pre aria-hidden="true"
      style="position: absolute; visibility: hidden; white-space: pre; font-family: freight-sans-pro, Arial; font-size: 14px; font-style: normal; font-variant: normal; font-weight: 400; word-spacing: 0px; letter-spacing: normal; text-indent: 0px; text-rendering: auto; text-transform: none;"></pre>
  </label>
  <input type="submit" class="search-submit" value="Search">
</form>

Text Content

Skip to content


STRATECHERY BY BEN THOMPSON

On the business, strategy, and impact of technology.

Menu
 * About
 * Dithering
 * Exponent

Search for:




BY BEN THOMPSON

 * About
 * Dithering
 * Exponent


THE DAILY UPDATE

About The Daily Update
Subscribe: Monthly | Annual
Member Forum


FOLLOW

Create an account to receive
Weekly Updates via
Email, Podcast, or RSS


EXPLORE STRATECHERY

 * Concepts
 * Companies
 * Topics


ARCHIVES

 * Articles
 * Daily Updates
 * Years in Review


ACCOUNT

 * Member
 * Delivery Preferences
 * Manage Account
 * Sign Out

 * Log In
 * Sign Up

Loading


SUPPORT

Please email support@stratechery.com


SUBSCRIBER’S DAILY UPDATE

Thursday, August 25, 2022


AN INTERVIEW WITH JAY GOLDBERG ABOUT THE CHIP SLOWDOWN, INTEL AND NVIDIA, AND
THE CHIPS ACT

Wednesday, August 24, 2022


THE TWITTER WHISTLEBLOWER, MDAUS AND BOTS, MUSK’S AKORN LIFELINE

Tuesday, August 23, 2022


GOOGLE, MACHINE LEARNING, AND CSAM; TAKEAWAYS AND TRADEOFFS; APPLE’S CSAM
CONTROVERSEY

Monday, August 22, 2022


HOUSE OF THE DRAGON AND CREATIVE PROGRAMMING, THE BIG TEN’S DEAL, DISNEY’S NEW
PRICES


INSTAGRAM, TIKTOK, AND THE THREE TRENDS

Posted onTuesday, August 16, 2022Wednesday, August 17, 2022

Back in 2010, during my first year of Business School, I helped give a
presentation entitled “Twitter 101”:



My section was “The Twitter Value Proposition”, and after admitting that yes,
you can find out what people are eating for lunch on Twitter, I stated “The
truth is you can find anything you want on Twitter, and that’s a good thing.”
The Twitter value proposition was that you could “See exactly what you need to
see, in real-time, in one place, and nothing more”; I illustrated this by
showing people how they could unfollow me:



The point was that Twitter required active management of your feed, but if you
put in the effort, you could get something uniquely interesting to you that was
incredibly valuable.

Most of the audience didn’t take me up on it.

FACEBOOK VERSUS INSTAGRAM

If there is one axiom that governs the consumer Internet — consumer anything,
really — it is that convenience matters more than anything. That was the problem
with Twitter: it just wasn’t convenient for nearly enough people to figure out
how to follow the right people. It was Facebook, which digitized offline
relationships, that dominated the social media space.

Facebook’s social graph was the ultimate growth hack: from the moment you
created an account Facebook worked assiduously to connect you with everyone you
knew or wish you knew from high school, college, your hometown, workplace, you
name an offline network and Facebook digitized it. Of course this meant that
there were far too many updates and photos to keep track of, so Facebook ranked
them, and presented them in a feed that you could scroll endlessly.

Users, famously, hated the News Feed when it was first launched: Facebook had
protesters outside their doors in Palo Alto when it was introduced, and far more
online; most were, ironically enough, organized on Facebook. CEO Mark Zuckerberg
penned an apology:

> We really messed this one up. When we launched News Feed and Mini-Feed we were
> trying to provide you with a stream of information about your social world.
> Instead, we did a bad job of explaining what the new features were and an even
> worse job of giving you control of them. I’d like to try to correct those
> errors now…

The errors to be corrected were better controls over what might be shared;
Facebook did not give the users what they claimed to want, which was abolishing
the News Feed completely. That’s because the company correctly intuited a
significant gap between its users stated preference — no News Feed — and their
revealed preference, which was that they liked News Feed quite a bit. The next
fifteen years would prove the company right.

It was hard to not think of that non-apology apology while watching Adam
Mosseri’s Instagram update three weeks ago; Mosseri was clear that videos were
going to be an ever great part of the Instagram experience, along with
recommended posts. Zuckerberg reiterated the point on Facebook’s earnings call,
noting that recommended posts in both Facebook and Instagram would continue to
increase. A day later Mosseri told Casey Newton on Platformer that Instagram
would scale back recommended posts, but was clear that the pullback was
temporary:

> “When you discover something in your feed that you didn’t follow before, there
> should be a high bar — it should just be great,” Mosseri said. “You should be
> delighted to see it. And I don’t think that’s happening enough right now. So I
> think we need to take a step back, in terms of the percentage of feed that are
> recommendations, get better at ranking and recommendations, and then — if and
> when we do — we can start to grow again.” (“I’m confident we will,” he added.)

Michael Mignano calls this recommendation media in an article entitled The End
of Social Media:

> In recommendation media, content is not distributed to networks of connected
> people as the primary means of distribution. Instead, the main mechanism for
> the distribution of content is through opaque, platform-defined algorithms
> that favor maximum attention and engagement from consumers. The exact type of
> attention these recommendations seek is always defined by the platform and
> often tailored specifically to the user who is consuming content. For example,
> if the platform determines that someone loves movies, that person will likely
> see a lot of movie related content because that’s what captures that person’s
> attention best. This means platforms can also decide what consumers won’t see,
> such as problematic or polarizing content.
> 
> It’s ultimately up to the platform to decide what type of content gets
> recommended, not the social graph of the person producing the content. In
> contrast to social media, recommendation media is not a competition based on
> popularity; instead, it is a competition based on the absolute best content.
> Through this lens, it’s no wonder why Kylie Jenner opposes this change; her
> more than 360 million followers are simply worth less in a version of media
> dominated by algorithms and not followers.

Sam Lessin, a former Facebook executive, traced this evolution from the analog
days to what is next in a Twitter screenshot entitled “The Digital Media
‘Attention’ Food Chain in Progress”:



Lessin’s five steps:

>  1. The Pre-Internet ‘People Magazine’ Era
>  2. Content from ‘your friends’ kills People Magazine
>  3. Kardashians/Professional ‘friends’ kill real friends
>  4. Algorithmic everyone kills Kardashians
>  5. Next is pure-AI content which beats ‘algorithmic everyone’

This is a meta observation and, to make a cheap play on words, the first reason
why it made sense for Facebook to change its name: Facebook the app is eternally
stuck on Step 2 in terms of entertainment (the app has evolved to become much
more of a utility, with a focus on groups, marketplace, etc.). It’s Instagram
that is barreling forward. I wrote last summer about Instagram’s Evolution:

> The reality, though, is that this is what Instagram is best at. When Mosseri
> said that Instagram was no longer a photo-sharing app — particularly a “square
> photo-sharing app” — he was not making a forward-looking pronouncement, but
> simply stating what has been true for many years now. More broadly, Instagram
> from the very beginning — including under former CEO Kevin Systrom — has been
> marked first and foremost by evolution.

To put this in Lessin’s framework, Instagram started out as a utility for adding
filters to photos put on other social networks, then it developed into a social
network in its own right. What always made Instagram different than Facebook,
though, is the fact that its content was default-public; this gave the space for
the rise of brands, meme and highlight accounts, and the Instagram influencer.
Sure, some number of people continued to use Instagram primarily as a social
network, but Meta, more than anyone, had an understanding of how Instagram usage
had evolved over time.



In other words, when Kylie Jenner posts a petition demanding that Meta “Make
Instagram Instagram again”, the honest answer is that changing Instagram is the
most Instagram-like behavior possible.

THREE TRENDS

Still, it’s understandable why Instagram did back off, at least for now: the
company is attempting to navigate three distinct trends, all at the same time.

The first trend is the shift towards ever more immersive mediums. Facebook, for
example, started with text but exploded with the addition of photos. Instagram
started with photos and expanded into video. Gaming was the first to make this
progression, and is well into the 3D era. The next step is full immersion —
virtual reality — and while the format has yet to penetrate the mainstream this
progression in mediums is perhaps the most obvious reason to be bullish about
the possibility.



The second trend is the increase in artificial intelligence. I’m using the term
colloquially to refer to the overall trend of computers getting smarter and more
useful, even if those smarts are a function of simple algorithms, machine
learning, or, perhaps someday, something approaching general intelligence. To go
back to Facebook, the original site didn’t have any smarts at all: it was just a
collection of profile pages. Twitter came along and had the timeline, but the
only smarts there was the ability to read a time stamp: all of the content was
presented in chronological order. What made Facebook’s News Feed work was the
application of ranking: from the very beginning the company tried to present
users the content from their network that it thought you might be most
interested in, mostly using simple signals and weights. Over time this ranking
algorithm has evolved into a machine-learning driven model that is constantly
iterating based on every click and linger, but on the limited set of content
constrained by who you follow. Recommendations is the step beyond ranking: now
the pool is not who you follow but all of the content on the entire network; it
is a computation challenge that is many orders of magnitude beyond mere ranking
(and AI-created content another massive step-change beyond that).



The third trend is the change in interaction models from user-directed to
computer-controlled. The first version of Facebook relied on users clicking on
links to visit different profiles; the News Feed changed the interaction model
to scrolling. Stories reduced that to tapping, and Reels/TikTok is about
swiping. YouTube has gone further than anyone here: Autoplay simply plays the
next video without any interaction required at all.



One of the reasons Instagram got itself in trouble over the last few months is
by introducing changes along all of these vectors at the same time. The company
introduced more video into the feed (Trend 1), increased the percentage of
recommended posts (Trend 2), and rolled out a new version of the app that was
effectively a re-skinned TikTok to a limited set of users (Trend 3). It stands
to reason that the company would have been better off doing one at a time.

That, though, would only be a temporary solution: it seems likely that all of
these trends are inextricably intertwined.

MEDIUM, COMPUTING, AND INTERACTION MODELS

Start with medium: text is easy, which is why it was the original medium of the
Internet; effectively anyone can create it. The first implication is that there
is far more text on the Internet than anything else; it also follows that the
amount of high quality text is correspondingly high as well (a small fraction of
a large number is still very large). The second implication has to do with AI:
it is easier to process and glean insight from text. Text, meanwhile, takes
focus and the application of an acquired skill for humans to interpret, not
dissimilar to the deliberate movement of a mouse to interact with a link.

Photos used to be more difficult: digital cameras came along around the same
time as the web, but even then you needed to have a dedicated device, move those
photos to your computer, then upload them to a network. What is striking about
the impact of smartphones is that not only did they make the device used to take
pictures the same device used to upload and consume them, but they actually made
it easier to take a picture than to write text. Still, it took time for AI to
catch up: at first photos were ranked using the metadata surrounding them; only
over the last few years has it become possible for services to understand what
the photo actually is. The most reliable indicator of quality — beyond a like —
remains the photo that you stop at while scrolling.

The ease of making a video followed a similar path to photos, but more extreme:
making and uploading your own videos before the smartphone was even more
difficult than photos; today the mechanics are just as easy, and it’s arguably
even easier to make something interesting, given the amount of information
conveyed by a video relative to photos, much less a text. Still, videos require
more of a commitment than text or photos, because consuming them takes time;
this is where the user interaction layer really matters. Lessin again, in
another Twitter screenshot:



> I saw someone recently complaining that Facebook was recommending to them…a
> very crass but probably pretty hilarious video. Their indignant response [was
> that] “the ranking must be broken.” Here is the thing: the ranking probably
> isn’t broken. He probably would love that video, but the fact that in order to
> engage with it he would have to go proactively click makes him feel bad. He
> doesn’t want to see himself as the type of person that clicks on things like
> that, even if he would enjoy it.
> 
> This is the brilliance of Tiktok and Facebook/Instagram’s challenge: TikTok’s
> interface eliminates the key problem of what people want to view themselves as
> wanting to follow/see versus what they actually want to see…it isn’t really
> about some big algorithm upgrade, it is about relesing emotional inner tension
> for people who show up to be entertained.

This is the same tension between stated and revealed preference that Facebook
encountered so many years ago, and its exactly why I fully expect the company
to, after this pullback, continue to push forward with all three of the
Instagram changes it is exploring.

INSTAGRAM’S RISK

Still, there is considerably more risk this time around: when Facebook pushed
forward with the News Feed it was the young upstart moving aside incumbents like
MySpace; it’s not as if its userbase was going to go backwards. This case is the
opposite: Instagram is clearly aping TikTok, which is the young upstart in the
space. It’s possible its users decide that if they must experience TikTok, they
might as well go for the genuine thing.

This also highlights why TikTok is a much more serious challenge than Snapchat
was: in that case Instagram’s network was the sword used to cut Snapchat off at
the knees. I wrote in The Audacity of Copying Well:

> For all of Snapchat’s explosive growth, Instagram is still more than double
> the size, with far more penetration across multiple demographics and
> international users. Rather than launch a “Stories” app without the network
> that is the most fundamental feature of any app built on sharing, Facebook is
> leveraging one of their most valuable assets: Instagram’s 500 million
> users…Instagram and Facebook are smart enough to know that Instagram Stories
> are not going to displace Snapchat’s place in its users lives. What Instagram
> Stories can do, though, is remove the motivation for the hundreds of millions
> of users on Instagram to even give Snapchat a shot.

Instagram has no such power over TikTok, beyond inertia; in fact, the
competitive situation is the opposite: if the goal is not to rank content from
your network, but to recommend videos from the best creators anywhere, then it
follows that TikTok is in the stronger relative position. Indeed, this is why
Mosseri spent so much time talking about “small creators” with Newton:

> I think one of the most important things is that we help new talent find an
> audience. I care a lot about large creators; I would like to do better than we
> have historically by smaller creators. I think we’ve done pretty well by large
> creators overall — I’m sure some people will disagree, but in general, that’s
> what the data suggests. I don’t think we’ve done nearly as well helping new
> talent break. And I think that’s super important. If we want to be a place
> where people push culture forward, to help realize the promise of the
> internet, which was to push power into the hands of more people, I think that
> we need to get better at that.

There is the old Internet AMA question as to whether you would rather fight a
horse-sized duck or 100 duck-sized horses. The analogy here is that in a world
of ranking a horse-sized duck that everyone follows is valuable; in a world of
recommendations 100 duck-sized horses are much more valuable, and Instagram is
willing to sacrifice the former for the latter.

META’S REWARD

The payoff, though, will not be “power” for these small creators: the
implication of entertainment being dictated by recommendations and AI instead of
reputation and ranking is that all of the power accrues to the platform doing
the recommending. Indeed, this is where the potential reward comes in: this
power isn’t only based on the sort of Aggregator dynamics underpinning dominant
platforms today, but also absolutely massive amounts of investment in the
computing necessary to power the AI that makes all of this possible.

In fact, you can make the case that if Meta survives the TikTok challenge, it
will be on its way to the sort of moat enjoyed by the likes of Apple, Amazon,
Google, and Microsoft, all of which have real world aspects to their
differentiation. There is lots of talk about the $10 billion the company is
spending on the Metaverse, but that is R&D; the more important number for this
moat is the $30 billion this year in capital expditures, most of which is going
to servers for AI. That AI is doing recommendations now, but Meta’s moat will
only deepen if Lessin is right about a future where creators can be taken out of
the equation entirely, in favor of artificially-generated content.

What is noteworty is that AI content will be an essential part of any sort of
Metaverse future; I wrote earlier this year in DALL-E, the Metaverse, and Zero
Marginal Content:

> What is fascinating about DALL-E is that it points to a future where these
> three trends can be combined. DALL-E, at the end of the day, is ultimately a
> product of human-generated content, just like its GPT-3 cousin. The latter, of
> course, is about text, while DALL-E is about images. Notice, though, that
> progression from text to images; it follows that machine learning-generated
> video is next. This will likely take several years, of course; video is a much
> more difficult problem, and responsive 3D environments more difficult yet, but
> this is a path the industry has trod before:
> 
>  * Game developers pushed the limits on text, then images, then video, then 3D
>  * Social media drives content creation costs to zero first on text, then
>    images, then video
>  * Machine learning models can now create text and images for zero marginal
>    cost
> 
> In the very long run this points to a metaverse vision that is much less
> deterministic than your typical video game, yet much richer than what is
> generated on social media. Imagine environments that are not drawn by artists
> but rather created by AI: this not only increases the possibilities, but
> crucially, decreases the costs.

These AI challenges, I would add, apply to monetization as well: one of the
outcomes of Apple’s App Tracking Transparency changes is that advertising needs
to shift from a deterministic model to a probabilistic one; the companies with
the most data and the greatest amount of computing resources are going to make
that shift more quickly and effectively, and I expect Meta to be top of the
list.

None of this matters, though, without engagement. Instagram is following the
medium trend to video, and Meta’s resources give it the long-term advantage in
AI; the big question is which service users choose to interact with. To put it
another way, Facebook’s next two decades are coming into sharper focus than
ever; it is how well it navigates the TikTok minefield over the next two years
that will determine if that long-term vision becomes a reality.

I wrote a follow-up to this Article in this Daily Update.


POLITICAL CHIPS

Posted onWednesday, August 3, 2022Thursday, August 4, 2022

Last Friday AMD surpassed Intel in market capitalization:



This was the second time in history this happened — the first was earlier this
year — and it may stick this time; AMD, in stark contrast to Intel, had stellar
quarterly results. Both stocks are down in the face of a PC slump, but that is
much worse news for Intel, given that they make worse chips.

It’s also not a fair comparison: AMD, thirteen years on from its spinout of
Global Foundries, only designs chips; Intel both designs and manufactures them.
It’s when you include AMD’s current manufacturing partner, TSMC, that Intel’s
relative decline becomes particularly apparent:



Of course an Intel partisan might argue that this comparison is unfair as well,
because TSMC manufactures chips for a whole host of companies beyond AMD. That,
though, is precisely Intel’s problem.

INTEL’S STUMBLE

The late Clay Christensen, in his 2004 book Seeing What’s Next, predicted
trouble for Intel:

> Intel’s well-honed processes — which are almost unassailable competitive
> strengths in fights for undershot customers hungering for performance
> increases — might inhibit its ability to fight for customers clamoring for
> customized products. Its exacting manufacturing process could hamper its
> ability to deliver customized products. Its sales force could have difficulty
> adapting to a very different sales cycle. It would have to radically alter its
> marketing process. The VCE model predicts that operating “fast fabs” will be
> an attractively profitable point in the value chain in the future. The good
> news for IDMs such as IBM and Intel is that they own fabs. The bad news is
> that their fabs aren’t fast. Entrants without legacy processes could quite
> conceivably develop better proprietary processes that can rapidly deliver
> custom processors.

This sounds an awful lot like what happened over the ensuing years: one of
TSMC’s big advantages is its customer service. Given the fact that the company
was built as a pure play foundry it has developed processes and off-the-shelf
building blocks that make it easy for partners to build custom chips. This was
tremendously valuable, even if the resultant chips were slower than Intel’s.

What Christensen didn’t foresee was that Intel would lose the performance crown;
rather, he assumed that performance would cease to be an important
differentiator:

> If history is any guide, motivated innovators will continue to do the
> seemingly impossible and find unanticipated ways to extend the life of Moore’s
> Law. Although there is much consternation that at some point Moore’s Law will
> run into intractable physical limits, the only thing we can predict for
> certain is that innovators will be motivated to figure out solutions.
> 
> But this does not address whether meeting Moore’s Law will continue to be
> paramount to success. Everyone always hopes for the emergence of new,
> unimagined applications. But the weight of history suggests the unimagined
> often remains just that; ultimately ever more demanding applications will stop
> appearing or will emerge much more slowly than anticipated. But even if new,
> high-end applications emerge, rocketing toward the technological frontier
> almost always leaves customers behind. And it is in those overshot tiers that
> disruptions take root.
> 
> How can we tell if customers are overshot? One signal is customers not using
> all of a product’s functionality. Can we see this? There are ever-growing
> populations of users who couldn’t care less about increases in processing
> power. The vast majority of consumers use their computers for word processing
> and e-mail. For this majority, high-end microprocessors such as Intel’s
> Itanium and Pentium 4 and AMD’s Athlon are clearly overkill. Windows XP runs
> just fine on a Pentium III microprocessor, which is roughly half as fast as
> the Pentium 4. This is a sign that customers may be overshot.

Obviously Christensen was wrong about a Pentium III being good enough, and not
just because web pages suck; rather, the infinite malleability of software
really has made it possible to not just create new kinds of applications but to
also substantially rework previous analog solutions. Moreover, the need for more
performance is actually accelerating with the rise of machine-learning based
artificial intelligence.

Intel, despite being a chip manufacturer, understood the importance of software
better than anyone. I explained in a Daily Update earlier this year about how
Pat Gelsinger, then a graduate student at Stanford, convinced Intel to stick
with a CISC architecture design because that gave the company a software
advantage; from an oral history at the Computer Museum:

> Gelsinger: We had a mutual friend that found out that we had Mr. CISC working
> as a student of Mr. RISC, the commercial versus the university, the old versus
> the new, teacher versus student. We had public debates of John and Pat. And
> Bear Stearns had a big investor conference, a couple thousand people in the
> audience, and there was a public debate of RISC versus CISC at the time, of
> John versus Pat.
> 
> And I start laying out the dogma of instruction set compatibility,
> architectural coherence, how software always becomes the determinant of any
> computer architecture being developed. “Software follows instruction set.
> Instruction set follows Moore’s Law. And unless you’re 10X better and John,
> you’re not 10X better, you’re lucky if you’re 2X better, Moore’s Law will just
> swamp you over time because architectural compatibility becomes so dominant in
> the adoption of any new computer platform.” And this is when x86– there was no
> server x86. There’s no clouds at this point in time. And John and I got into
> this big public debate and it was so popular.
> 
> Brock: So the claim wasn’t that the CISC could beat the RISC or keep up to
> what exactly but the other overwhelming factors would make it the winner in
> the end.
> 
> Gelsinger: Exactly. The argument was based on three fundamental tenets. One is
> that the gap was dramatically overstated and it wasn’t an asymptotic gap.
> There was a complexity gap associated with it but you’re going to make it leap
> up and that the CISC architecture could continue to benefit from Moore’s Law.
> And that Moore’s Law would continue to carry that forward based on simple
> ones, number of transistors to attack the CISC problems, frequency of
> transistors. You’ve got performance for free. And if that gap was in a
> reasonable frame, you know, if it’s less than 2x, hey, in a Moore’s Law’s term
> that’s less than a process generation. And the process generation is two years
> long. So how long does it take you to develop new software, porting operating
> systems, creating optimized compilers? If it’s less than five years you’re
> doing extraordinary in building new software systems. So if that gap is less
> than five years I’m going to crush you John because you cannot possibly
> establish a new architectural framework for which I’m not going to beat you
> just based on Moore’s Law, and the natural aggregation of the computer
> architecture benefits that I can bring in a compatible machine. And, of
> course, I was right and he was wrong.

That last sentence needs a caveat: Gelsinger was right when it came to computers
and servers, but not smartphones. There performance wasn’t free, because
manufacturers had to be cognizant of power consumption. More than cognizant, in
fact — power usage was the overriding concern. Tony Fadell, who created the iPod
and led the development of the first three generations of the iPhone, told me in
an interview earlier this year:

> You have to have that point of view of that every nanocoulomb is sacred and
> compatibility doesn’t matter, we’re going to use the best bits, but we’re not
> going to make sure it has to be the same look and feel. It doesn’t have to
> have the same principles that is designed for a laptop or a standalone desktop
> computer, and then bring those down to something that’s smaller form factor,
> and works within a certain envelope. You have to rethink all the principles.
> You might use the bits around, and put them together in different ways and use
> them differently. That’s okay. But your top concept has to be very, very
> different about what you’re building, why you’re building it, what you’re
> solving, and the needs of that new environment, which is mobile, and mobile at
> least for a day or longer for that battery life.

The key phrase there is “compatibility doesn’t matter”; Gelsinger’s argument for
CISC over RISC rested on the idea that by the time you remade all of the
software created for CISC, Intel would have long since overcome the performance
delta between different architectures via its superior manufacturing, which
would allow compatibility to trump the competition. Smartphones, though,
provided a reason to build up the software layer from scratch, with efficiency,
not performance, as the paramount goal.


1



All of this still fit in Christensen’s paradigm, I would note: foundries like
TSMC and Samsung could accommodate new chip designs that prioritized efficiency
over performance, just as Christensen predicted. What he didn’t foresee in 2004
was just how large the smartphone market would be. While there are a host of
reasons why TSMC took the performance crown from Intel over the last five years,
a major factor is scale: TSMC was making so many chips that it had the money and
motivation to invest in Moore’s Law.

The most important decision was shifting to extreme ultraviolet lithography at a
time when Intel thought it was much too expensive and difficult to implement;
TSMC, backed by Apple’s commitment to buy the best chips it could make,
committed to EUV in 2014, and delivered the first EUV-derived chips in 2019 for
the iPhone.

Those EUV machines are made by one company — ASML. They’re worth more than Intel
too (and Intel is a customer):



The Dutch company, to an even greater degree than TSMC, is the only lithography
maker that can afford to invest in the absolute cutting edge.

FROM TECHNOLOGY TO ECONOMICS

In 2021’s Internet 3.0 and the Beginning of (Tech) History, I posited that the
first era of the Internet was defined by technology, i.e. figuring out what was
possible. Much of this technology, including standards like TCP/IP, DNS, HTTP,
etc. was developed decades ago; this era culminated in the dot com bubble.

The second era of the Internet was about economics, specifically the
unprecedented scale possible in a world of zero distribution costs.

> Unlike the assumptions that undergird Internet 1.0, it turned out that the
> Internet does not disperse economic power but in fact centralizes it. This is
> what undergirds Aggregation Theory: when services compete without the
> constraints of geography or marginal costs, dominance is achieved by
> controlling demand, not supply, and winners take most.
> 
> Aggregators like Google and Facebook weren’t the only winners though; the
> smartphone market was so large that it could sustain a duopoly of two
> platforms with multi-sided networks of developers, users, and OEMs (in the
> case of Android; Apple was both OEM and platform provider for iOS). Meanwhile,
> public cloud providers could provide back-end servers for companies of all
> types, with scale economics that not only lowered costs and increased
> flexibility, but which also justified far more investments in R&D that were
> immediately deployable by said companies.

Chip manufacturing obviously has marginal costs, but the fixed costs are so much
larger that the economics are not that dissimilar to software (indeed, this is
why the venture capital industry, which originated to support semiconductor
startups, so seamlessly transitioned to software); today TSMC et al invest
billions of dollars into a single fab that generates millions of chips for
decades.

That increase in scale is why a modular value chain ultimately outcompeted
Intel’s integrated approach, and it’s why TSMC’s position seems so impregnable:
sure, a chip designer like MediaTek might announce a partnership with Intel to
maybe produce some lower-end chips at some point in the future, but there is a
reason it is not a firm commitment and not for the leading edge. TSMC, for at
least the next several years, will make the best chips, and because of that will
have the most money to invest in what comes next.

Scale, though, is not the end of the story. Again from Internet 3.0 and the
Beginning of (Tech) History:

> This is why I suspect that Internet 2.0, despite its economic logic predicated
> on the technology undergirding the Internet, is not the end-state…After
> decades of developing the Internet and realizing its economic potential, the
> entire world is waking up to the reality that the Internet is not simply a new
> medium, but a new maker of reality…
> 
> To the extent the Internet is as meaningful a shift [as the printing press] —
> and I think it is! — is inversely correlated to how far along we are in the
> transformation that will follow — which is to say we have only gotten started.
> And, after last week, the world is awake to the stakes; politics — not
> economics — will decide, and be decided by, the Internet.

Time will tell if my contention that an increasing number of nations will push
back against American Internet hegemony by developing their own less efficient
but independent technological capabilities is correct; one could absolutely make
the case that the U.S.’s head start is so overwhelming that attempts to undo
Silicon Valley centralization won’t pan out anywhere other than China, where
U.S. Internet companies have been blocked for a generation.

Chips, though, are very much entering the political era.

POLITICS AND THE END-STATE

Taiwan President Tsai Ing-wen shared, as one does, some pictures from lunch on
social media:



The man with glasses and the red tie in the first picture is Morris Chang, the
founder of TSMC; behind him is Mark Liu, TSMC’s chairman. They were the first
guests listed in President Tsai’s write-up of the lunch with House Speaker Nancy
Pelosi, which begins:

> 台灣與美國共享的,不只有民主自由人權的價值,在經濟發展和民主供應鏈的合作上,我們也持續共同努力。
> 
> Taiwan and the United States not only share the values of democracy, freedom
> and human rights, but also continue to work together on economic development
> and democratic supply chains.

That sentence captures why Taiwan looms so large, not only on the occasion of
Pelosi’s visit, but to world events for years to come. Yes, the United States
supports Taiwan because of democracy, freedom and human rights; the biggest
reason why that support may one day entail aircraft carriers is because of chips
and TSMC. I wrote two years ago in Chips and Geopolitics:

> The international status of Taiwan is, as they say, complicated. So, for that
> matter, are U.S.-China relations. These two things can and do overlap to make
> entirely new, even more complicated complications.
> 
> Geography is much more straightforward:
> 
> 
> 
> Taiwan, you will note, is just off the coast of China. South Korea, home to
> Samsung, which also makes the highest end chips, although mostly for its own
> use, is just as close. The United States, meanwhile, is on the other side of
> the Pacific Ocean. There are advanced foundries in Oregon, New Mexico, and
> Arizona, but they are operated by Intel, and Intel makes chips for its own
> integrated use cases only.
> 
> The reason this matters is because chips matter for many use cases outside of
> PCs and servers — Intel’s focus — which is to say that TSMC matters. Nearly
> every piece of equipment these days, military or otherwise, has a processor
> inside. Some of these don’t require particularly high performance, and can be
> manufactured by fabs built years ago all over the U.S. and across the world;
> others, though, require the most advanced processes, which means they must be
> manufactured in Taiwan by TSMC.
> 
> This is a big problem if you are a U.S. military planner. Your job is not to
> figure out if there will ever be a war between the U.S. and China, but to plan
> for an eventuality you hope never occurs. And in that planning the fact that
> TSMC’s foundries — and Samsung’s — are within easy reach of Chinese missiles
> is a major issue.
> 
> China, meanwhile, is investing heavily in catching up, although Semiconductor
> Manufacturing International Corporation (SMIC), its Shanghai-based champion,
> only just started manufacturing on a 14nm process, years after TSMC, Samsung,
> and Intel. In the long run, though, the U.S. faced a scenario where China had
> its own chip supplier, even as it threatened the U.S.’s chip supply chain.

This reality is why I ultimately came down in support of the CHIPS Act, which
passed Congress last week. I wrote in a Daily Update:

> This is why Intel’s shift to being not simply an integrated device
> manufacturer but also a foundry is important: yes, it’s the right thing to do
> for Intel’s business, but it’s also good for the West if Intel can pull it
> off. That, by extension, is why I’m fine with the CHIPS bill favoring
> Intel…AMD, Qualcomm, Nvidia, et al, are doing just fine under the current
> system; they are drivers and beneficiaries of TSMC’s dominance in particular.
> The system is working! Which, to the point above, is precisely why Intel being
> helped disproportionately is in fact not a flaw but a feature: the goal should
> be to counteract the fundamental forces pushing manufacturing to
> geopolitically risky regions, and Intel is the only real conduit available to
> do that.

Time will tell if the CHIPS Act achieves its intended goals; the final version
did, as I hoped, explicitly limit investment by recipients in China, which is
already leading chip makers to rethink their investments. That this is warping
the chip market is, in fact, the point: the structure of technology drives
inexorably towards the most economically efficient outcomes, but the ultimate
end state will increasingly be a matter of politics.

I wrote a follow-up to this Article in this Daily Update.

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

 1. As an example of how efficiency trumped performance, the first iPhone’s
    processor was actually underclocked — better battery life was more of a
    priority than faster performance. 


BIG TEN BLAME

Posted onTuesday, July 12, 2022Wednesday, July 13, 2022

Penn State has always been a usurper, at least to me.

In 1984 the Supreme Court ruled that the NCAA’s attempt to control individual
universities’ college football TV rights was an illegal restraint on trade;
while the lawsuit was instigated by the University of Oklahoma, it was
conferences that were the biggest beneficiary, as it simply made more sense to
negotiate TV rights as a collective of similarly situated schools. This was a
problem for independent Penn State; its traditional rivals like Pitt, Syracuse,
and Boston College joined the basketball-focused Big East, leaving the football
power to make overtures to the Big Ten.

The 1990 announcement that Penn State was joining the conference was a
controversial one within the Big Ten itself. A fair number of the conference’s
athletic directors were opposed to the move, and most of the coaches (it is
university presidents that make the decision, and even there Penn State only
received the minimum 7 votes in favor); I was a 10 year-old sports fan of a
then-decrepit football team in Wisconsin that had nothing going for it other
than Big Ten pride, and resented the idea that Penn State was going to come in
and potentially dominate the conference.

It all feels quite quaint here in 2022, and not just because Wisconsin has had
more football success than Penn State; the Big Ten added Nebraska in 2011, and
Maryland and Rutgers in 2014, in both cases setting off seismic shifts in the
college landscape. Both expansions made sense on the edges, both figuratively
and literally: Nebraska was a traditional football power neighboring Iowa that,
more importantly, gave the conference the 12 teams necessary to stage a
lucrative conference championship game. Maryland and Rutgers bordered
Pennsylvania — Penn State was a well-established member of the Big Ten by this
point, in practice if not in my mind — and, more importantly, brought the
Washington D.C. and New York City markets to the Big Ten’s groundbreaking cable
TV network.

It is the latest expansion announcement, though, that blows apart the entire
concept of a regional conference founded on geographic rivalries: UCLA and USC
will join the Big Ten in 2024. They are not, needless to say, in a Big Ten
border state:



That, though, very much fits the reality of 2022: geography doesn’t matter, but
attention does, and after the SEC grabbed Texas and Oklahoma last year, the two
Los Angeles universities represented the two biggest programs not yet in the two
biggest conferences. As for the timing, it’s all about TV: the Big Ten is in the
middle of negotiating new rights packages this summer, while the Pac-12’s rights
package ends in 2024. One thing is for sure: everyone in college sports,
particularly those who, like 10-year-old me, value tradition, know exactly who
to blame:



This appears to be true as far as the mechanics of the Big Ten’s expansion: Fox
reportedly instigated the UCLA and USC talks with the Big Ten. Figuring out why
it was Fox, though — and ESPN with the SEC — exculpates both networks from
ultimate responsibility.

A BRIEF HISTORY OF TV

TV’s origins are, unsurprisingly, in radio: thanks to the magic of over-the-air
broadcasting a radio station could deliver audio to anyone in its geographic
area with a compatible listening device. Originally all of said audio was
generated at the radio station, but given that most people wanted to listen to
similar things, it made sense to link stations together and broadcast the same
content all at once. In 1928 NBC became the first coast-to-coast radio network,
linking together radio stations with phone lines; those stations weren’t owned
by NBC, but were rather affiliates: local owners would actually operate the
stations and sell local ads, and pay a fee to NBC for content that, because it
was funded by stations across the country, was far more compelling than anything
that could be produced locally.

TV followed the same path: thanks to the increased cost of producing video
relative to audio, the economic logic of centralized content production was even
more compelling (as were the proceeds from selling ads nationally). The content
was more compelling as well, leading to further innovation in distribution,
specifically the advent of cable that I wrote about earlier this year. That new
distribution led to further innovation in content: new networks were created
specifically for cable, even though cable had originally been created to help
people receive over-the-air broadcasts.

In fact, new cable networks were so compelling that local broadcast stations
(particularly those unaffiliated with the national networks) were worried about
losing carriage, leading the FCC to institute “must-carry” rules that compelled
cable networks to carry local broadcast networks for free. However, in the 1980s
must-carry rules were ruled by a federal Appeals Court to be an infringement on
the cable carriers’ First Amendment rights, threatening local broadcast networks
that depended on the rules for access to an increasingly large percentage of
homes.

This ruling was an impetus for the Cable Television Consumer Protection and
Competition Act of 1992, which among other provisions, gave local broadcast
stations the choice between must-carry status or charging retransmission fees;
if the station chose the latter, then they forewent the former. This led to a
clear bifurcation in broadcast channels: cheap and mostly local programming
chose must-carry, while stations with the most desirable programming — which per
the aforementioned point, were affiliated with national networks — chose the
latter. Those national networks took notice: a significant part of the increase
in cable fees over the last thirty years has been driven by national networks
increasing the fees they charge affiliates for programming; those affiliates
recoup those fees by increasing their retransmission fees (cable companies, for
their part, continue to break out these fees on bills — my “Broadcast TV
Surcharge” in Wisconsin is $21/month).

Local stations originally pushed back against this shift, de-affiliating with
networks that pushed too hard. The problem, though, came back to content:
networks had everything from popular sitcoms and dramas to national news to late
night talk shows. The most important bit of content, though, was sports.
Moreover, the importance of sports has only increased as those other content
offerings have been unbundled by the Internet: streaming services have sitcoms
and dramas, websites have all of the news you could ever want to consume, and
social media provides all kinds of comedy and commentary; the one exception to
Internet disruption are live games between teams you care about.

FOX’S CONTRARIAN BET

The importance of sports to ESPN is self-explanatory: the entire point of the
network is to show games, particularly as its SportsCenter and talk show
franchises have suffered from competition with the Internet. ESPN’s parent
company, Disney, has jumped into this competition with both feet, launching
Disney+ and taking a controlling stake in Hulu.

That controlling stake came from a deal that Disney announced in 2017: the
company acquired the majority of 21st Century Fox, including: its film and
television studios, most of its cable TV networks (including FX), a controlling
stake in National Geographic, Star India, and the aforementioned stake in Hulu.
Disney’s rationale was that it needed to beef up its content offerings to
compete in streaming, which was clearly the future; traditional TV was, by
implication, the past.

That left a newly spun-out Fox Corporation, which included the Fox broadcast
network, Fox News, and Fox Sports (including the Fox Sports cable channels and
Fox’s share in the Big Ten network); the nature of these channels signaled a
completely different strategy than streaming. I wrote at the time in a Daily
Update:

> In that last sentence I actually put forth two distinct strategies: selling
> direct to consumers, and charging distributors significantly more. Both do
> depend on having differentiated content, which was the point of that Daily
> Update, but the similarities end there. To explain what I mean, this deal
> actually offers two great examples: if it goes through, that means Fox is
> pursuing the second strategy, and Disney the first.
> 
> Start with Fox: its news and sports divisions — particularly the former — are
> highly differentiated. That gives Fox significant pricing power with
> shrinking-but-still-very-large TV distributors. Moreover, given that both news
> and sports are heavily biased towards live viewing, they are also a good fit
> for advertising, which again, matches up with traditional TV distribution.
> What Fox would accomplish with this deal, then, is shedding a huge amount of
> that detritus I mentioned earlier: sure, more was better when there was only
> one distributor, but now that there is competition for viewer’s attention,
> filler is a drag on the content that actually gives negotiating leverage. Fox
> could come out of this deal with the same pricing power it has today but a
> vastly streamlined corporate structure and cost basis.

It’s a bet that has paid off: while Disney, like other streaming companies,
enjoyed a huge run-up during the pandemic, it is Fox that today has the superior
returns in its two years as an independent company:



Still, I think my original analysis was incomplete; Fox isn’t simply wringing
more money out of a dying business model with a leaner corporate structure.
Rather, it is driving the paid-TV business model to its logical endpoint:
nothing but sports and news. That doesn’t mean, though, they are the biggest
winner.

SPORTS CONCENTRATION

The foundation of Fox’s offering is the NFL, but it is an expensive offering:
$2.025 billion per year for Sunday afternoon regular season games, playoffs, and
the Super Bowl every four years. The NFL understands its position in the sports
landscape very well — it has a monopoly on the professional version of America’s
favorite sport — and it prices its rights accordingly, even as it is careful to
spread its games across multiple networks:


1





College football is America’s second favorite sport; it has also traditionally
been a much more profitable one for the networks. CBS, for example, currently
pays the SEC $55 million per year to broadcast the conference’s top games, which
average over 6 million viewers per telecast; that is about a third of what CBS
averages for NFL games, but at a fraction of the cost for rights. The relative
cheapness of that deal is explained by the fact it was negotiated a decade ago,
when the college football landscape was considerably more diffused:


2





The SEC’s new deal looks a lot different: ESPN has exclusive rights to SEC
football


3 for $300 million per year. That increase is driven by the SEC’s dominance of
college football, and corresponding national interest; that interest will be
that much greater thanks to the addition of Texas and Oklahoma (which will
almost certainly lead to an increase in rights fees). In short, sports are the
biggest driver of pay-TV, which means it is essential to have the sports the
most people want to watch; the SEC figures prominently in that regard.



Still, it is the Big Ten, based in the sports-obsessed Midwest, and filled with
massive public universities churning out interested alumni who live all over the
country, that is the most attractive of all; even before this expansion the
conference was rumored to be seeking a deal for $1.1 billion/year. Add in the
Los Angeles market and UCLA and USC fan bases and that number could end up even
higher.

BLAME GAMES

Put all of these pieces together, and the question of who exactly is responsible
for college football’s conference upheavel gets a bit more complicated:

 * Local TV stations charge ever higher retransmission fees to pay-TV operators
   because they have compelling content that subscribers demand.
 * Networks charge ever higher affiliate fees to TV stations for that compelling
   content, extracting most (if not all) of those retransmission fees.
 * The most compelling content is sports, especially as alternative content
   loses out to the Internet, and the most popular sport (the NFL) is governed
   by a single entity, allowing it to extract the greatest fees.

All of this extraction is a function of relative bargaining power that is
ultimately derived from what fans want to see:



Given this, the logic of the Big Ten’s expansion into California is obvious: the
more of an audience that the Big Ten can command, the more of the money flowing
through that value chain it can extract. Sure, it’s not quite to the level of
the NFL, but it’s the next closest thing. This is also the downside to Fox’s bet
on live: while the company owns the content it produces on channels like Fox
News, it has to buy sports rights, and it is the Big Ten that is determined to
take its share, even if that means an expansion that otherwise makes no sense at
all.

In other words, I think the tweet above has it backwards: Fox and ESPN are not
“grandmasters calling the shots behind the scenes”; they are essential but
ultimately replaceable parts in the movement of money from consumers to the
entities that provide the content those consumers want.



Still, the tweet is instructive: perhaps the most essential role Fox and ESPN
play for universities is taking the blame as the latter make more money than
ever.

I wrote a follow-up to this Article in this Daily Update.

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

 1. The NFL is also very careful about cultivating local fans: the league has
    always insisted that all games are available over-the-air in local markets,
    whether they are on broadcast TV or not 

 2. The SEC also sold secondary rights to ESPN 

 3. And basketball, but that doesn’t drive rights fees to nearly the same
    extent 


SPOTIFY, NETFLIX, AND AGGREGATION

Posted onMonday, June 27, 2022Tuesday, June 28, 2022

When Spotify filed for its direct listing in 2018, it was popular to compare the
streaming music service to Netflix, the streaming video service; after all, both
were quickly growing subscription-based services that gave consumers media on
demand. This comparison was intended as a bullish one for Spotify, given that
Netflix’s stock had increased by 1,113% over the preceding five years:



The problem with the comparison is that Spotify clearly was a different kind of
business than Netflix, thanks to its very different relationship to its content
providers; whereas Netflix had always acquired content on a wholesale basis —
first through licensing deals with content owners, and later by making its own
content — Spotify licensed content on a revenue share basis. This latter point
is why I was skeptical of Spotify’s profit-making potential; I wrote at the time
in Lessons From Spotify, in a section entitled Spotify’s Missing Profit
Potential:

> That, though, is precisely the problem: Spotify’s margins are completely at
> the mercy of the record labels, and even after the rate change, the company is
> not just unprofitable, its losses are growing, at least in absolute euro
> terms:
> 
> 
> 
> Moreover, it seems highly unlikely Spotify’s Cost of Revenue will improve much
> in the short-term: those record deals are locked in until at least next year,
> and they include “most-favored nation” provisions, which means that Spotify
> has to get Universal Music Group, Sony Music Entertainment, Warner Music
> Group, and Merlin (the representative for many independent labels), which own
> 85% of the music on Spotify as measured by streams, to all agree to reduce
> rates collectively. Making matters worse, the U.S. Copyright Royalty Board
> just increased the amount to be paid out to songwriters; Spotify said the
> change isn’t material, but it certainly isn’t in the right direction either.

I compared this (unfavorably) to Netflix in a follow-up:

> Netflix has licensed content, not agreed-to royalty agreements. That means
> that Netflix’s costs are fixed, which is exactly the sort of cost structure
> you want if you are a growing Internet company. Spotify, on the other hand,
> pays the labels according to a formula that has revenue as the variable, which
> means that Spotify’s marginal costs rise in-line with their top-line revenue.

Both companies proceeded to do quite well in the markets over the next
three-and-a-half years, with a decided edge to Netflix; however, the last six
months undid all of those gains, with Netflix getting hit harder than Spotify:



Setting aside any analysis of absolute value, I think the relative trend is
justified: I still maintain, as I did in 2018, that Spotify and Netflix are
fundamentally different businesses because of their relationship to content;
now, though, I think that Spotify’s position is preferable to Netflix, and has
more long-term upside. Moreover, I don’t think this is a new development: I was
wrong in 2018 to prefer Netflix to Spotify; worse, I should have already known
why.

CATEGORIZING AGGREGATORS

In my original article about Aggregation Theory I wrote:

> The value chain for any given consumer market is divided into three parts:
> suppliers, distributors, and consumers/users. The best way to make outsize
> profits in any of these markets is to either gain a horizontal monopoly in one
> of the three parts or to integrate two of the parts such that you have a
> competitive advantage in delivering a vertical solution. In the pre-Internet
> era the latter depended on controlling distribution…
> 
> The fundamental disruption of the Internet has been to turn this dynamic on
> its head. First, the Internet has made distribution (of digital goods) free,
> neutralizing the advantage that pre-Internet distributors leveraged to
> integrate with suppliers. Secondly, the Internet has made transaction costs
> zero, making it viable for a distributor to integrate forward with end
> users/consumers at scale.
> 
> 
> 
> This has fundamentally changed the plane of competition: no longer do
> distributors compete based upon exclusive supplier relationships, with
> consumers/users an afterthought. Instead, suppliers can be commoditized
> leaving consumers/users as a first order priority. By extension, this means
> that the most important factor determining success is the user experience: the
> best distributors/aggregators/market-makers win by providing the best
> experience, which earns them the most consumers/users, which attracts the most
> suppliers, which enhances the user experience in a virtuous cycle.

Fast forward to 2017, where in Defining Aggregators I sought to provide a more
specific definition of an Aggregator; specifically, Aggregators had:

 * A direct relationship with users
 * Zero marginal costs for serving users
 * Demand-driven multi-sided networks with decreasing acquisition costs

The rest of the post was devoted to building a taxonomy of Aggregators based on
their relationships to suppliers:

 * Level 1 Aggregators paid for supply, but had superior buying power due to
   their user base; Netflix was here.
 * Level 2 Aggregators incurred marginal transaction costs for adding supply;
   “real-world” companies like Uber and Airbnb were here.
 * Level 3 Aggregators had zero supply costs; Google and Facebook were here.

Notice the tension between the two articles, specifically this sentence in
Aggregation Theory: “no longer do distributors compete based upon exclusive
supplier relationships”. Had I kept that sentence in mind then I ought to have
concluded that Level 1 and Level 2 were not Aggregators at all: sure, companies
in these categories could scale on the demand side, but they were going to hit a
wall on the supply side. Indeed, this has been a problem for Uber in particular:
the company has never been able to escape from the need to compete for supply,
which is another way of saying the company has never been able to make any
money.

Netflix has a similar problem: the company’s content investments have failed to
provide the evergreen lift in customer acquisition I anticipated; despite having
more original content than ever, Netflix has hit the wall in terms of subscriber
growth, particularly in developed countries where it can charge the highest
prices. While some of these challenges were forseeable — I predicted that
Netflix would have a rough stretch where all of its once-content providers tried
their hand at streaming


1 — it does seem likely that Netflix is going to struggle to get significantly
more leverage on its content costs than it has to date, as that is the only way
to not just acquire but also keep its subscribers.



In short, Defining Aggregator was focused on the demand-side in its definition
and the supply-side in its taxonomy; my original
Article — and, in retrospect, the better one — did the opposite. The only way
you can truly control demand — the tell-tale sign of an Aggregator — is to have
fully commoditized and infinitely scalable supply; streaming video fails on the
former, and ride-sharing on the latter.

SPOTIFY AND COMMODITIZED SUPPLY

With that in mind, go back to the reason I was skeptical of Spotify, and those
revenue-sharing deals with record labels. In 2017’s The Great Unbundling I noted
that the music industry, much to the surprise of anyone who observed the Napster
era, had ended up in pretty good shape:

> While piracy drove the music labels into the arms of Apple, which unbundled
> the album into the song, streaming has rewarded the integration of back
> catalogs and new music with bundle economics: more and more users are willing
> to pay $10/month for access to everything, significantly increasing the
> average revenue per customer. The result is an industry that looks remarkably
> similar to the pre-Internet era:
> 
> 
> 
> Notice how little power Spotify and Apple Music have; neither has a sufficient
> user base to attract suppliers (artists) based on pure economics, in part
> because they don’t have access to back catalogs. Unlike newspapers, music
> labels built an integration that transcends distribution.

It’s easy to see why this would be a bad thing for Spotify; on the flipside, you
can see why many of the most optimistic assumptions about Spotify’s upside
rested on the company somehow eliminating the labels completely, even though the
fact that new music immediately becomes back catalog music means that the
label’s relative position in the music value chain is quite stable. This is why
I’ve always been skeptical about the possibility of Spotify displacing the
labels entirely, and the short-lived exclusive wars confirmed that point of
view: it’s better for artists and labels for all music to be available
everywhere.

My contention — and the key insight undergirding this Article — is that this is
better for Spotify, as well. Go back to the point about commoditization: an
input does not need to be free to be commoditized. Sure, the marginal cost of
streaming music — which is nothing but bits — is zero; it is a credit to the
music labels’ new-music-to-back-catalog flywheel that they are able to charge
for access to these bits. At the same time, the bits are available to anyone for
roughly the same price: that is why not just Spotify and Apple, but also
YouTube, Amazon, Tidal, Deezer, etc. all have roughly the same catalog for
roughly the same price. Streaming music isn’t free, but it is an infinitely
available non-exclusive commodity.

Look again at the contrast to the other companies I highlighted above: there are
a limited number of potential ride-share drivers, which means that Uber has to
compete with Lyft with a never-ending set of driver incentives that make
profitability difficult if not impossible to achieve; Netflix has some of the
content — not all of it — and it has to bid against competitors to get more of
it.

This does, to be clear, make it easier to achieve a direct profit: as I noted
above, because Netflix pays a fixed cost for content it can earn a surplus
without having to pay anything extra to the content producer, whereas Spotify
can only eke out profitability from its subscribers by reducing its operational
costs. The real opportunity for an Aggregator, though, is building a business
model that is independent of supply and instead predicated on owning demand.
Here Spotify is better placed than Netflix — although the latter is finally
making moves in that direction.

SPOTIFY’S INVESTOR DAY

Earlier this month Spotify had an investor day (which I covered in an Update
last week); Charlie Hellman, vice president and head of music product, presented
a textbook case as to why Spotify is an Aggregator for music, with the business
model to match. Hellman started by emphasizing Spotify’s role in new music
discovery:



> It’s important to remember that first and foremost Spotify is a music company.
> All of our music team’s strategies ladder up to two primary goals: making a
> unique and superior music experience for fans, and creating a more open and
> valuable ecosystem for artists. These two goals really complement one another,
> which is clear to see when you look at the playlisting ecosystem we’ve spent
> the last decadee defining and perfecting. Whatever your mood, your style,
> whatever the occassion, Spotify has something for you, and as Gustav
> mentioned, Spotify drives around 22 billion discoveries a month. On top of
> that, 1/3 of all new artist discoveries happen on personalized algorithmic
> playlists. Listeners love this exposure to new music, as well as the
> personalized touch. Discovery is our bread and butter, and it’s driving a
> level of engagement that no streaming service can claim.

This is the number one characteristic of an Aggregator: in a world of scarcity
distribution was the most valuable; in a world of abundance it is discovery that
matters most. To that end, Hellman emphasized that the world of digital music
was one of ever-increasing abundance, thanks in part to Spotify:



> The music industry is changing fast. There have never been fewer barriers to
> entry, and that’s enabling more and more talented artists to be discovered…but
> with this reduction in barriers comes an increase in the number of artists
> seeking success. We’re in the midst of an explosion in creativity where tens
> of thousands of songs are uploaded each day, and that rate of daily uploads
> has doubled in the last two years. In this rapidly growing landscape, artists
> need an evolving toolkit that works for the millions who will make up
> tomorrow’s music industry. One that mirrors their creativity and ambition by
> offering speed and scale.

Hellman highlighted free tools Spotify offers, including analytics, custom art
and videos, and the ability to pitch your song for a playlist. What is far more
important from a business perspective, though, is the fact you can pay for
promotion.



> In addition to these free tools, we’ve also invested in building the most
> performant and effective commercial tools for promotion in the streaming era.
> Because there’s so much being added to Spotify every day, artists need tools
> that will help them stand out, now more than ever, and we’re uniqely
> positioned to deliver effective promotion for artists for a few reasons.
> First, unlike like, say, social media marketing, our promotion tools reach
> people that have already actively made a decision to open Spotify and listen
> to music. It’s contextual. Plus, our ability to target listeners based on
> their listening activity, their taste, is second to none. And further, we have
> the unique ability to actually report back how many people listened to or
> saved the music as a result. Our ability to deliver the best promotional
> opportunities for artists presents a tremendous opportunity.

This is an opportunity that is paying off; CFO Paul Vogel explained how
Spotify’s heavy investments in podcasting (more on this in a moment) were
obscuring major improvements in the financial performance of the company’s music
business:



> Our music business has been a real source of strength, driving strong revenue
> growth, and strong margin expansion. This may not be immediately evident in
> our consolidated results, but make no mistake, we have delivered against the
> expectations and framework we rolled out at the time of our direct listing.
> Isolating just the performance of our music operations, you’d see that our
> music revenues, which consist of premium subscriptions, ad-supported music,
> our marketplace suite of artist tools, and strategic licensing, great at a 24%
> compound annual growth rate, in-line with our expectations on an FX-neutral
> basis, and importantly, our music gross margins have increased over the same
> time frame, reaching 28.3% in 2021. This is approximately 150-basis points
> higher than our total 2021 consolidated margin of 26.8%…Looking at our
> progression in another way, since 2018, the last year before our major podcast
> investment, our music margins have expanded on average by approximately 75
> basis points per year. At our last investor day we told you to expect gross
> margins in the 30-35% range over the long-term. This was, and still remains,
> the goal for our music operations. As you can see from these numbers, we are
> clearly on our way.
> 
> Let me unpack how we have expanded our music gross margins. At the beginning
> of 2018, we announced the development of our marketplace business — all of the
> tools and services that Charlie described earlier. Our thesis back then was
> that by providing increased value to artists, creators, and labels, they would
> see material benefit, and so would Spotify, and that is exactly what we are
> seeing today. We’ve long maintained that our success is not solely tied to
> renegotiating new headline rates. It’s about our ability to innovate, right
> along with our partners, to grow a business that benefits both artists and
> Spotify, and that’s what we’ve done with Marketplace. In 2018 our Marketplace
> contribution to gross profit was only $20 million. In 2021 it grew to $160
> million, 8x the size in just four years. We expect that number to increase
> another 30% or more in 2022. We see tremendous upside in Marketplace, and
> anticipate that it’s financial contribution will continue to grow at a healthy
> double-digit rate in the years ahead. Marketplace is the quintessential
> example of our approach to capital allocation. There was a significant
> up-front cost to build-and-launch these offerings, but we saw compelling data
> which gave us the confidence to double-down and invest aggressively against
> our goals. It may have taken time to build up momentum, but our patience and
> conviction has paid off, and we are seeing material benefit from our
> investment.

Notice how this business — in its mechanics, if not its financial numbers —
looks more like a Google or a Facebook than a Netflix: Spotify isn’t earning
money by making margin on its content spend; rather, it is seeking to enable
more content than ever, confident that it controls the best means to surface the
content users want. Those means can then be sold to the highest bidder, with all
of the margin going to Spotify. Spotify calls this promotion — it certainly
looks a lot like the old radio model of pay-to-play — but that’s really just
another word for advertising. Moreover, this isn’t Spotify’s only advertising
business: the company has long been building an ad-supported music business, and
is now heavily investing in doing the same for podcasting (which has always
clearly been an aggregation strategy).

ACTING LIKE AN AGGREGATOR

Being an Aggregator is not the only way to make money; indeed, it is amongst the
most difficult. It is far more straightforward to make a differentiated product
and charge for it; that is also the only possibility for most products and
companies. What makes Aggregators unique is that they are best served by doing
the opposite of what is optimal for traditional businessess:

 * Instead of having differentiated content, Aggregators want commoditized
   content, and more of it.
 * Instead of increasing margin on their users, Aggregators want to reduce it,
   ideally to zero, or at least to the same level as their competitors (as in
   the case of Spotify).
 * Instead of introducing friction in the market, the better to lock-in users,
   Aggregators want to decrease friction, confident the gravitational pull of
   their user experience will, all things being equal, draw in more users than
   their competitors, increasing their attractivness to not just suppliers but
   also advertisers (who, in the case of Spotify’s music business, may be the
   same entities).

Spotify has, for the most part, acted like an Aggregator: the company has fought
exclusives in the music business, kept its subscription prices as low as
possible, and in the case of podcasts ensured its Anchor platform supports all
podcast players.


2 Netflix has not: the company has invested heavily in its own content, steadily
increases its prices, and is now embarking on a campaign to make sure its best
customers pay more for sharing access.



What is noteworthy are the exceptions: on Spotify’s side the most obvious one
are its podcast exclusives. The potential payoff in terms of taking podcast
share is obvious; being an Aggregator means being the biggest player in a
particular space, and by all accounts Spotify’s strategy has delivered exactly
that. There are, though, risks in the approach: exclusive content creators are
liable to become ever more expensive over time as they seek to seize their share
of the value they create. Moreover, they risk triggering a response by
competitors making their own exclusive deals. To put it in the terms discussed
above, exclusive content is de-commoditized content, and that is bad for
Aggregators (that noted, Spotify’s biggest long-term competitor is not Apple but
YouTube, a formidable Aggregator in its own right; maybe exclusives aren’t the
worst idea).

Netflix, meanwhile, is finally building — or contracting to build — an ad
business. While this still seems like a reaction to slowing growth instead of a
considered strategy, what is important is the shift from selling exclusive
supply to selling exclusive demand: the latter is far more scalable and
defensible, although the transition will be very dificult (and may not fully pay
off if Netflix isn’t willing to invest on its own).

The takeaway I am most interested in, though, is a selfish one: I had an
essential part of Aggregation Theory — the commoditzation of supply — right
originally, only to forget that insight and make several bad calls along the
way. In the case of Netflix and Spotify I was right in observing that they were
different businesses; my mistake was mislabeling which had more potential as an
Aggregator.

I wrote a follow-up to this Article in this Daily Update.

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

 1. What I got wrong about my prediction was the timing, thanks to COVID. 

 2. Spotify has also ensured that independent podcasters like Stratechery can
    deliver their content on Spotify. 


DATA AND DEFINITIONS

Posted onTuesday, June 21, 2022Tuesday, June 21, 2022

Last week the German Bundeskartellamt (“Federal Cartel Office”) announced in a
press release:

> The Bundeskartellamt has initiated a proceeding against the technology company
> Apple to review under competition law its tracking rules and the App Tracking
> Transparency Framework. In particular, Apple’s rules have raised the initial
> suspicion of self-preferencing and/or impediment of other companies, which
> will be examined in the proceeding.

The press release quoted Andreas Mundt, the President of the Bundeskartellamt,
who stated:

> We welcome business models which use data carefully and give users choice as
> to how their data are used. A corporation like Apple which is in a position to
> unilaterally set rules for its ecosystem, in particular for its app store,
> should make pro-competitive rules. We have reason to doubt that this is the
> case when we see that Apple’s rules apply to third parties, but not to Apple
> itself. This would allow Apple to give preference to its own offers or impede
> other companies.

The press release continues:

> Already based on the applicable legislation, and irrespective of Apple’s App
> Tracking Transparency Framework, all apps have to ask for their users’ consent
> to track their data. Apple’s rules now also make tracking conditional on the
> users’ consent to the use and combination of their data in a dialogue popping
> up when an app not made by Apple is started for the first time, in addition to
> the already existing dialogue requesting such consent from users. The
> Identifier for Advertisers, classified as tracking, which is important to the
> advertising industry and made available by Apple to identify devices, is also
> subject to this new rule. These rules apparently do not affect Apple when
> using and combining user data from its own ecosystem. While users can also
> restrict Apple from using their data for personalised advertising, the
> Bundeskartellamt’s preliminary findings indicate that Apple is not subject to
> the new and additional rules of the App Tracking Transparency Framework.

John Gruber disagrees at Daring Fireball:

> I think this is a profound misunderstanding of what Apple is doing, and how
> Apple is benefiting indirectly from ATT. Apple’s privacy and tracking rules do
> apply to itself. Apple’s own apps don’t show the track-you-across-other-apps
> permission alert not because Apple has exempted itself but because Apple’s own
> apps don’t track you across other apps. Apple’s own apps show privacy report
> cards in the App Store, too…
> 
> If you want to argue that Apple engaged in this entire ATT endeavor to benefit
> its own Search Ads platform, that’s plausible too. But if Apple actually cared
> more about maximizing Search Ads revenue than it does user privacy, wouldn’t
> they have just engaged in actual user tracking? The Bundeskartellamt
> perspective here completely disregards the idea that surveillance advertising
> is inherently unethical and Apple has studiously avoided it for that reason,
> despite the fact that it has proven to be wildly profitable for large
> platforms.

This strikes me as a situation where Gruber — my co-host for Dithering — is
right on the details, even as the Bundeskartellamt is right on the overall
thrust of the argument. The distinction comes down to definitions.

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

It’s striking in retrospect how little time Apple spent publicly discussing its
App Tracking Transparency (ATT) initiative — a mere 20 seconds at WWDC 2020,
wedged in between updates about camera-in-use indicators and privacy labels in
the App Store:



> Next, let’s talk about tracking. Safari’s Intelligent Tracking Prevention has
> been really successful on the web, and this year, we wanted to help you with
> tracking in apps. We believe tracking should always be transparent, and under
> your control, so moving forward, App Store policy will require apps to ask
> before tracking you across apps and websites owned by other companies.

These 20 seconds led, 19 months later, to Meta announcing a $10 billion revenue
shortfall, the largest but by no means only significant retrenchment in the
online advertising space. Not everyone was hurt, though: Google and Amazon, in
particular, have seen their share of digital advertising increase, and, as
Gruber admitted, Apple has benefited as well; the Financial Times reported last
fall:

> Apple’s advertising business has more than tripled its market share in the six
> months after it introduced privacy changes to iPhones that obstructed rivals,
> including Facebook, from targeting ads at consumers. The in-house business,
> called Search Ads, offers sponsored slots in the App Store that appear above
> search results. Users who search for “Snapchat”, for example, might see TikTok
> as the first result on their screen. Branch, which measures the effectiveness
> of mobile marketing, said Apple’s in-house business is now responsible for 58
> per cent of all iPhone app downloads that result from clicking on an advert. A
> year ago, its share was 17 per cent.

These numbers, derived as they are from app analytics companies, are certainly
fuzzy, but they are the best we have given that Apple doesn’t break out revenue
numbers for its advertising business; they are also from last fall, before ATT
really began to bite. They also exclude the revenue Apple earns from Google for
being the default search engine for Safari, and while Google’s earnings indicate
YouTube has suffered from ATT, search has more than made up for it.

I explained in depth why these big companies have benefitted from ATT in
February’s Digital Advertising in 2022; I wrote in the context of Amazon
specifically:

> Amazon also has data on its users, and it is free to collect as much of it as
> it likes, and leverage it however it wishes when it comes to selling ads. This
> is because all of Amazon’s data collection, ad targeting, and conversion
> happen on the same platform — Amazon.com, or the Amazon app. ATT only
> restricts third party data sharing, which means it doesn’t affect Amazon at
> all…
> 
> That is not to say that ATT didn’t have an effect on Amazon: I noted above
> that Snap’s business did better than expected in part because its business
> wasn’t dominated by direct response advertising to the extent that Facebook’s
> was, and that more advertising money flowed into other types of advertising.
> This almost certainly made a difference for Amazon as well: one of the most
> affected areas of Facebook advertising was e-commerce; if you are an
> e-commerce seller whose Shopify store powered-by Facebook ads was suddenly
> under-performing thanks to ATT, then the natural response is to shift products
> and advertising spend to Amazon.

This is where definitions matter. The opening paragraph of Apple’s Advertising &
Policy page, housed under the “apple.com/legal” directory, states:

> Ads that are delivered by Apple’s advertising platform may appear on the App
> Store, Apple News, and Stocks. Apple’s advertising platform does not track
> you, meaning that it does not link user or device data collected from our apps
> with user or device data collected from third parties for targeted advertising
> or advertising measurement purposes, and does not share user or device data
> with data brokers.

I note the URL path for a reason: the second sentence of this paragraph has
multiple carefully selected words — and those word choices not only impact the
first sentence, but may, soon enough, lead to its expansion. Specifically:

“MEANING”

Apple’s advertising platform does not track you, meaning that it does not link
user or device data collected from our apps with user or device data collected
from third parties for targeted advertising or advertising measurement purposes,
and does not share user or device data with data brokers.

“Tracking” is not a neutral term! My strong suspicion — confirmed by anecdata —
is that a lot of the most ardent defenders of Apple’s ATT policy are against
targeted advertising as a category, which is to say they are against companies
collecting data and using that data to target ads. For these folks I would
imagine tracking means exactly that: the collection and use of data to target
ads. That certainly seems to align with the definition of “track” from macOS’s
built-in dictionary: “Follow the course or trail of (someone or something),
typically in order to find them or note their location at various points”.

However, this is not Apple’s definition: tracking is only when data Apple
collects is linked with data from third parties for targeted advertising or
measurement, or when data is shared/sold to data brokers. In other words, data
that Apple collects and uses for advertising is, according to Apple, not
tracking; the privacy policy helpfully lays out exactly what that data is
(thanks lawyers!):

> We create segments, which are groups of people who share similar
> characteristics, and use these groups for delivering targeted ads. Information
> about you may be used to determine which segments you’re assigned to, and
> thus, which ads you receive. To protect your privacy, targeted ads are
> delivered only if more than 5,000 people meet the targeting criteria.
> 
> We may use information such as the following to assign you to segments:
> 
>  * Account Information: Your name, address, age, gender, and devices
>    registered to your Apple ID account. Information such as your first name in
>    your Apple ID registration page or salutation in your Apple ID account may
>    be used to derive your gender. You can update your account information on
>    the Apple ID website.
>    
>    
> 
>  * Downloads, Purchases & Subscriptions: The music, movies, books, TV shows,
>    and apps you download, as well as any in-app purchases and subscriptions.
>    We don’t allow targeting based on downloads of a specific app or purchases
>    within a specific app (including subscriptions) from the App Store, unless
>    the targeting is done by that app’s developer.
> 
>  * Apple News and Stocks: The topics and categories of the stories you read
>    and the publications you follow, subscribe to, or turn on notifications
>    from.
> 
>  * Advertising: Your interactions with ads delivered by Apple’s advertising
>    platform.
> 
> When selecting which ad to display from multiple ads for which you are
> eligible, we may use some of the above-mentioned information, as well as your
> App Store searches and browsing activity, to determine which ad is likely to
> be most relevant to you. App Store browsing activity includes the content and
> apps you tap and view while browsing the App Store. This information is
> aggregated across users so that it does not identify you. We may also use
> local, on-device processing to select which ad to display, using information
> stored on your device, such as the apps you frequently open.

Just to put a fine point on this: according to Apple’s definition, collecting
demographic information, downloads/purchases/subscriptions, and browsing
behavior in Apple’s apps, and using that data to deliver targeted ads, is not
tracking, because all of the data is Apple’s (and by extension, neither is
Google’s collection and use of data from Safari search results, or Amazon’s
collection and use of data from its app; however, a developer associating an
in-app purchase with a Facebook ad is).

“AND”

Apple’s advertising platform does not track you, meaning that it does not link
user or device data collected from our apps with user or device data collected
from third parties for targeted advertising or advertising measurement purposes,
and does not share user or device data with data brokers.

One thing should be made clear: there has been a lot of bad behavior in the
digital ad industry. A particularly vivid example was reported by the Wall
Street Journal last month:

> The precise movements of millions of users of the gay-dating app Grindr were
> collected from a digital advertising network and made available for sale,
> according to people familiar with the matter. The information was available
> for sale since at least 2017, and historical data may still be obtainable, the
> people said. Grindr two years ago cut off the flow of location data to any ad
> networks, ending the possibility of such data collection today, the company
> said.
> 
> The commercial availability of the personal information, which hasn’t been
> previously reported, illustrates the thriving market for at-times intimate
> details about users that can be harvested from mobile devices. A U.S. Catholic
> official last year was outed as a Grindr user in a high-profile incident that
> involved analysis of similar data. National-security officials have also
> indicated concern about the issue: The Grindr data were used as part of a
> demonstration for various U.S. government agencies about the intelligence
> risks from commercially available information, according to a person who was
> involved in the presentation.
> 
> Clients of a mobile-advertising company have for years been able to purchase
> bulk phone-movement data that included many Grindr users, said people familiar
> with the matter. The data didn’t contain personal information such as names or
> phone numbers. But the Grindr data were in some cases detailed enough to infer
> things like romantic encounters between specific users based on their device’s
> proximity to one another, as well as identify clues to people’s identities
> such as their workplaces and home addresses based on their patterns, habits
> and routines, people familiar with the data said.

It’s difficult to defend any aspect of this, and this isn’t even a worst case
scenario: there are plenty of unscrupulous apps and ad networks that include
explicit Personal Identifiable Information (PII) in these data sales/transfers
as well; as Eric Suefert noted in 2020, the industry has had this reckoning
coming for a very long time.

That, though, is why the “and” from Apple is so meaningful; here is the sentence
again:

> Apple’s advertising platform does not track you, meaning that it does not link
> user or device data collected from our apps with user or device data collected
> from third parties for targeted advertising or advertising measurement
> purposes, and does not share user or device data with data brokers.

This definition conflates two very different things: linking and sharing. The
distinction between the two undergirded a regular feature of Meta CEO Mark
Zuckerberg’s appearances in Congressional hearings; here is a representative
exchange between Senator Edward Markey and Zuckerberg in 2018:



> Should Facebook get clear permission from users before selling or sharing
> sensitive information about your health, your finances, your relationships?
> Should you have to get their permission?…
> 
> Senator…I want to be clear: we don’t sell information. So regardless of
> whether we get permission to do that, that’s just not a thing we’re going to
> do.

Meta doesn’t sell data; it collects it, and the third parties that leverage the
company’s platforms for advertising very much prefer it that way. PII is like
radioactive material: it’s very valuable, and can certainly be leveraged, but
it’s also difficult to handle and can be dangerous to not just the users
identified but to the companies holding it. The way Meta works is that its
collective advertising base has effectively deputized the company to collect
data on their behalf; that data is not exposed directly, but is instead used to
deliver targeted advertisements that are by-and-large bought not by targeting
specific criteria, but rather by specifying desired results: app installs,
e-commerce conversions, etc. Everything user-related is, to the companies buying
the ads, a complete black box.

This is where linking comes in: apps or websites that leverage Facebook
advertising (or any other relevant advertising platform, like Snap) include a
Facebook SDK or Pixel that tracks installs, sales, etc., and sends that data to
Meta where it can be linked to an ad that was shown to that user. Again, this is
completely invisible to the developer or merchant; technically they are sending
data to Meta, since the conversion data was collected in their app or on their
website, but in reality it is Meta collecting that data and sending it to
themselves.

The reason why developers and merchants are happy with this arrangement is that
advertising is a scale business: you need a lot of data and a lot of customers
to make targeted advertising work, and no single developer or website has as
much scale as, say, a Google or an Amazon; Meta et al enable all of these
smaller developers and merchants to effectively work together without having to
know each other, or share data.



You can, to be clear, object to this arrangement, but it’s worth pointing out
that this is very different than selling or sharing data with data brokers; all
of the data is in one place and one place only, which is broadly similar to the
situation with Google or Amazon (or Apple, as I’ll get to in a moment). The big
difference is that Meta doesn’t own all of the customer touch points: whereas a
Meta advertiser may own their own Shopify website, an Amazon advertiser has to
list their goods on Amazon’s site, with all of the loss of control that entails.
Apple’s definition, though, lumps Meta’s approach (which again, is
representative of other platforms like Snap) in with the worst actors in the
space.

“OUR”

Apple’s advertising platform does not track you, meaning that it does not link
user or device data collected from our apps with user or device data collected
from third parties for targeted advertising or advertising measurement purposes,
and does not share user or device data with data brokers.

To the extent you think that the Bundeskartellamt is right, then it is this word
that is the most problematic definition of all. One would assume that “our”
means Apple-created apps, like News or Stocks: just as Amazon collects data from
the Amazon app, of course Apple collects data from its own apps. The actual
definition, though, is much more expansive; go back to the Epic trial and the
exchange I recounted in App Store Arguments:

> The argument that Judge Gonzales Rogers seemed the most interested in pursuing
> was one that Epic de-emphasized: Apple’s anti-steering provisions which
> prevent an app from telling a customer that they can go elsewhere to make a
> purchase. Apple’s argument, in this case presented by Cook, goes like this:
> 
> 
> 
> This analogy doesn’t work for all kinds of reasons; Apple’s ban is like Best
> Buy not allowing products in the store to have a website listed in the
> instruction manual that happens to sell the same products. In fact, as Nilay
> Patel noted, Apple does exactly this!
> 
> 
> 
> The point of this Article, though, is not necessarily to refute arguments, but
> rather to highlight them, and for me this was the most illuminating part of
> this case. The only way that this analogy makes sense is if Apple believes
> that it owns every app on the iPhone, or, to be more precise, that the iPhone
> is the store, and apps in the store can never leave.

Let me be precise in a different way that is relevant to this Article; Apple
doesn’t particularly care about or claim ownership of the content of an app on
the iPhone, but:

 * Apple insists that every app on the iPhone use its payment system for digital
   content
 * Apple treats all transactions made through its payment system as Apple data
 * Ergo, all transactions for digital content on the iPhone are Apple data

The end result looks something like this — i.e. strikingly similar to Facebook,
but with App Store payments attached:



Here’s the key point: when it comes to digital advertising, particularly for the
games that make up the vast majority of the app advertising industry,
transaction data is all that matters. All of the data that any platform
collects, whether that be Meta, Snap, Google, etc. is insignificant compared to
whether or not a specific ad led to a specific purchase, not just in direct
response to said ad, but also over the lifetime of the consumer’s usage of said
app. That is the data that Apple cut off with ATT (by barring developers from
linking it to their ad spend), and it is the same data that Apple has declared
is their own first party data, and thus not subject to its ban on “tracking.”

This, needless to say, is where legitimate questions about self-preferencing
come to the forefront. Developers who want to link conversion data with Facebook
are banned from doing so, while they have no choice but to share that data with
Apple because Apple controls app installation via the App Store; this strikes me
as a clear example of the President of the Bundeskartellamt’s claim that
“Apple’s rules apply to third parties, but not to Apple itself”.

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

I have been very clear that I disagree with those who want to ban all targeted
advertising; I believe that targeted advertising is an essential ingredient in a
new Internet economy that provides opportunities to small businesses serving
niches that are only viable when the world is your market. After all, people who
might love your product need some way to know that your product exists, and what
is compelling about platforms like Facebook is that it completely leveled the
advertising playing field: suddenly small businesses had the same tools and
opportunities to advertise as the biggest companies in the world. At the same
time, I understand and acknowledge those who disagree with the concept on
principle.

What is frustrating about the debate about ATT, though, is that Apple presents
itself as a representative of the latter, with its constant declarations that
privacy is a human right, and advertisements that lean heavily into the (truly
problematic) world of data brokering, even as it builds its own targeting
advertising business. Gruber asked me on this morning’s episode of Dithering
whether or not I would feel better about ATT if Apple weren’t itself doing
targeted advertising, and the answer is yes: I would still be disappointed about
the impact on the Internet economy, but at least it wouldn’t be so blatantly
anti-competitive.

Apple, to its credit, has made moves that very much align with its privacy
rhetoric by cleaning up some of the worst abuses by apps, including
significantly fine-tuning location permissions, providing a new weather
framework that makes it significantly cheaper to build a weather app (reducing
the incentive to monetize by selling location data), and increasing transparency
around data collection. Moreover, at this year’s WWDC the company introduced
significant enhancements to SKAdNetwork that should make it easier for
developers and platforms like Facebook to re-build their advertising
capabilities.

At the same time, an increasing number of signals suggest that Apple is set to
significantly expand their own advertising business; an obvious product to build
would be an ad network that runs in apps (given that these apps run on the
iPhone, Apple would in this scenario claim that collecting data about who saw
what ad would be first party data, just like transactions are). Yes, Apple tried
and failed to build an ad network previously, but a big reason that effort
failed is because Apple didn’t collect the sort of data necessary to make it
succeed.

What has changed is not just Apple, but also the data that matters: when iAd
launched in 2010, digital advertising ran like people still think it does,
leveraging relatively broad demographic categories and contextual information to
show a hopefully relevant ad;


1 what matters today is linking an ad to a transaction, and Apple has positioned
itself to have perfect knowledge of both, even as it denies others the same
opportunity.



--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

 1. This is the era when Facebook earned its reputation for being far too
    cavalier with user data; Facebook was also the company that built the modern
    advertising approach that depends on linking data instead of sharing it. 


ZERO-COVID AND FREE SPEECH

Posted onMonday, June 13, 2022Tuesday, June 14, 2022

From the Financial Times, last Thursday:

> Barely a week after the Chinese Communist party declared victory in its
> struggle to protect Shanghai from coronavirus, half of the financial hub’s
> districts will be shuttered this weekend to test millions of residents after
> signs emerged of renewed community transmission of the virus. China’s most
> populous city, which was only released from a two-month lockdown last week,
> detected 11 new infections on Thursday, six outside the city’s mass quarantine
> centres. The measures will affect eight of the financial hub’s 16 districts,
> including Pudong, one of the worst-hit areas at the start of the lockdown.
> 
> Three cases were detected in the Red Rose beauty parlour in the city centre,
> prompting health authorities to test more than 90,000 people close to the
> salon. Only a few days previously, the Xuhui local party body wrote a
> celebratory post on the microblogging platform Weibo hailing the salon’s
> reopening on June 1 for clients who had gone weeks without a professional
> haircut. It said the state-run salon’s resumption of business reflected how
> the city’s “pandemic situation improved”. The post has since been taken down.

The mass testing ended up finding 5 cases; Chaoyang district in eastern Beijing,
meanwhile, is undergoing mass testing of its own, and schools are closed.

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

One of the common responses to China’s draconian efforts to control COVID’s
spread (which, notably, do not include forced vaccination, or the use of Western
vaccines), is that it doesn’t work: SARS-CoV-2, particularly the Omicron
variant, is simply too viral. It’s worth pointing out that this response is
incorrect: China not only eventually controlled the Wuhan outbreak, and not only
kept SARS-CoV-2 out for most of 2021, but also ultimately controlled the
Shanghai outbreak as well. The fact there were only 5 community cases over the
weekend is proof that China’s approach works!

What I think people saying this mean is something different: either they believe
the trade-offs entailed in this effort are not worth it, or they simply can’t
imagine a government locking people in their homes for months, hauling citizens
off to centralized quarantine, separating parents and children, entering and
spraying their homes, and killing their pets. I suspect the latter is more
common, at least amongst most Westerners: people are so used to a baseline of
individual freedom and autonomy that the very possibility of the reality of
COVID in China simply does not compute.

TAIWAN AND ZERO-COVID

Perhaps it is not only my knowledge of China, but also my experience living in
Taiwan for nearly two decades, or more pertinently, my experience of living in
Taiwan the last two years, that makes me much more willing to believe in the
effectiveness of China’s approach.

For most of the last two-and-a-half years Taiwan was COVID-free; for most of
2020 that meant life went on as normal, with no masks, everything open, etc.;
the one abnormality was that every person entering Taiwan had to quarantine (at
home or in a hotel) for 14 days. Things changed in 2021, when the Alpha variant
broke through, leading to a soft lockdown: restaurants and schools were closed,
and workplaces were strongly encouraged to work from home; masks were instituted
everywhere, including outside, and quarantine was hotel only. What is less known
is that quarantine went beyond travelers: anyone who was a close contact of an
infected person, including family members and co-workers, but also people who
might have had the misfortune of being in the same restaurant at the same time
as a positive case, were quarantined as well (your location in said restaurant
was ascertained by reviewing your cellular location data).

It is this last point that, in my estimation, stopped the 2021 spread in its
tracks, and kept Taiwan COVID-free until earlier this year (I myself endured an
18-day centralized quarantine due to testing positive at the airport). It is
also, for nearly every Westerner I have relayed this fact to, a startling
abridgment of civil liberties. The very idea that you can be locked up for
simply being in the wrong place at the wrong time is inconceivable; that,
though, is much less stringent than China’s approach in Shanghai, including the
requirement that you need a PCR-test within the last 72 hours to even grocery
shop.

Here’s the thing: that relative reduction in stringency relative to China is
precisely why Taiwan’s containment eventually failed; Taiwan, for most of the
last month, has had the highest case rate in the world. From the New York Times
COVID tracker:


1





Taiwan, to its credit, did not lockdown in the face of this outbreak; I suspect
the horrors of the Shanghai lockdown served as a deterrent, particularly given
Taiwan’s ongoing struggle for international recognition and desire to
distinguish itself from China. It’s also worth noting that at the critical
moment — late March and early April — it wasn’t clear if China’s lockdowns would
work; still, even if the outcome was clear, Taiwan — despite its willingness to
violate civil liberties to a considerably greater degree than most Western
democracies — was never willing to go as far as China. And so, while the Chinese
approach worked, it almost certainly would not have worked in Taiwan simply
because the latter wasn’t willing to be as brutal as the former.

I am being, as best as I can, impartial about the choices here: the important
takeaway is not simply that China’s approach did in fact work to arrest the
spread of SARS-CoV-2, but also that it was the only approach that worked; even
Taiwan’s approach, which was far more stringent than any Western country would
tolerate, eventually failed. Of course there were benefits, particularly in
terms of getting time to administer vaccines, but it’s certainly worth wondering
if it was all worth it.


2



The opposite side of the spectrum were areas of America that, after enduring a
few months of (very) soft lockdown at the beginning of the pandemic, were mostly
open from the summer of 2020 on; I have friends in parts of Wisconsin, for
example, whose kids have been in school since the fall of 2020. The price of
this approach was far more deaths, particularly amongst the elderly who have
always been at far higher risk: over 1 million Americans have died of COVID.

This isn’t the complete COVID story, though, and not simply because there can be
no honest accounting of the pandemic until it finally sweeps China; the most
effective vaccines in the world were developed in the West, and the U.S.
produced and distributed the largest number of them. How many lives were saved,
and how much economic upheaval — which isn’t about simply dollars and cents, but
people’s livelihoods, sense of worth, and even sanity — was avoided or reduced
because of vaccines? That must be recorded in the ledger as well, and in this
accounting the West comes out looking far stronger.

THE GREAT FIREWALL

The reason to audit this accounting is that I think there is an analogy to be
drawn between COVID and the debates around free speech that have sprung up over
the last six years. Before then, there wasn’t much of a debate about free
speech: just as the W.H.O. and C.D.C. used to maintain that lockdowns don’t
work, it used to be widely accepted that free speech was a good thing. Moreover,
it was also accepted that free speech was not simply a legalistic limitation on
government power, but was a cultural value. I pointed out earlier this year that
this was no longer the case in elite culture; the debate around Elon Musk buying
Twitter confirmed exactly that.

To summarize, the “sophisticated” view on free speech is that the First
Amendment both restricts the government and also protects companies who make
their own moderation decisions; this is of course correct legally, but the idea
that this distinction should be both celebrated and pushed to its limit is new.
That, by extension, means that the “rube” view on free speech is that said
principle ought to apply broadly: not only should the government not be able to
limit your speech, but neither should Facebook or Twitter or Google. Again, this
was a widely held view not too long ago: much of the debate around net
neutrality, for example, centered on the importance of private corporations not
being allowed to treat different bits of data differently based on what type of
content they represented.

There are, of course, philosophical arguments to be made as to why either view
is better or worse than the other; to return to the COVID analogy, one can
debate whether or not the sacrifice of civil liberties is worth whatever deaths
might be prevented (again, with the caveat that the final accounting is not yet
complete). What I think is missing in both debates, though, is the question of
what was possible.

Go back to my point above: I strongly suspect that most people in the West are
convinced that China’s approach will not work — even though it is! — because
they simply cannot imagine enduring or tolerating or even encountering the level
of brutality necessary for success; that is certainly true of COVID dead-enders
who still bemoan that the West isn’t doing enough to control the spread of
COVID. It is, from my perspective, hard to imagine any of these folks accepting
non-negotiable centralized quarantine simply for being in the wrong restaurant
at the wrong time — and again, this is the Taiwan approach that ultimately
failed! They are complaining about something that simply isn’t possible, not
because their political enemies are unwilling to do what is necessary, but
because they themselves would never tolerate it.

This, I should note, is why I have long been in strong favor of fully opening
up: while there was an argument to be made that it was worth trying to delay
outbreaks until vaccines were widely available, by the summer of 2021 (in the
U.S.) the only possible outcome of restrictions was to make people miserable at
best, and cause economic, socio-political, and developmental damage at worst;
spread, absent a China-style approach, was inevitable, so why invite bad
outcomes when there are no benefits?


3



I have the same questions about free speech. Once again, I must acknowledge that
China’s approach to free speech works, at least in terms of its leaders’
immediate goals. In other words, it doesn’t exist, even — especially! — on the
Internet. This — like China’s insistence on zero-COVID — was something that
Westerners scoffed at as being unrealistic; then-President Bill Clinton said
upon the establishment of Permanent Normal Trade Relations with China:

> In the new century, liberty will spread by cell phone and cable modem. In the
> past year, the number of Internet addresses in China has more than quadrupled,
> from 2 million to 9 million. This year the number is expected to grow to over
> 20 million. When China joins the W.T.O., by 2005 it will eliminate tariffs on
> information technology products, making the tools of communication even
> cheaper, better, and more widely available. We know how much the Internet has
> changed America, and we are already an open society. Imagine how much it could
> change China.
> 
> Now there’s no question China has been trying to crack down on the Internet.
> Good luck! That’s sort of like trying to nail jello to the wall. But I would
> argue to you that their effort to do that just proves how real these changes
> are and how much they threaten the status quo. It’s not an argument for
> slowing down the effort to bring China into the world, it’s an argument for
> accelerating that effort. In the knowledge economy, economic innovation and
> political empowerment, whether anyone likes it or not, will inevitably go hand
> in hand.

Clinton, along with nearly all of the Western intelligentsia, underrated China’s
willingness to do whatever it took to build a mold around that jello, from
building the Great Firewall to employing countless numbers of censors to tanking
its entire IT sector once it felt it was becoming too politically powerful. The
end result is a populace that not only has little idea about today’s reality —
i.e. that most people have had COVID, and are fine, and are living normally —
but even less idea about the past.

TANK CAKE

Last February Time Magazine named Li Jiaqi one of its “Next Top 100 Most
Influential People”. Li’s nickname was the “lipstick king”, which refers to the
time in 2018 when the live-streaming e-commerce peddler sold 15,000 lipsticks in
5 minutes; last fall Li sold $1.7 billion worth of goods in 12 hours. Ten days
ago, on June 3, Li was doing what he does best — selling goods via
live-streaming — when his stream suddenly went off the air; Li, within a matter
of hours, was suddenly off of the Internet, no longer appearing on Taobao,
Alibaba’s e-commerce platform that streamed his show. The BBC explained what
happened:

> Last Friday night, Li was mid-way through his popular livestream show when it
> ended abruptly. The 30-year-old, known for his smooth voice and K-pop idol
> looks, had just shown his audience a vanilla log cake while selling snacks.
> The cake resembled a tank: it had Oreos for wheels and a wafer pipe resembling
> a cannon. And Li’s show was on 3 June, the eve of the 33rd anniversary of the
> Tiananmen Square massacre…
> 
> 
> 
> Generations of Chinese have grown up without learning of the massacre – and
> many of those millennials and Gen Z-ers appeared to be among Li’s audience on
> Friday and in the days after. Li failed to return to his livestreaming show
> after the transmission was cut. Shortly after, he posted on his Weibo account
> saying he had merely faced technical issues. But his continued absence – he
> has missed three shows so far during one of the year’s biggest online shopping
> festivals – has only fuelled more questions and debate. Some have cottoned on
> quickly as to why he was censored, while others are having a revelation. “What
> does the tank mean?” a confused viewer asked. Another said: “What could
> possibly be the wrong thing to say while selling snacks?”

That’s not all, though: it seems almost certain that Li had no idea he did
anything wrong, or why.

> Few online believe that Li was trying to make a political statement. Given his
> celebrity status, he knew how to navigate political sensitivities and to steer
> clear of minefields, they said. And he had never expressed political beliefs
> before. Some even argued that he was possibly among those who didn’t know
> about the Tiananmen Square massacre.
> 
> Many of his loyal fans also wondered if the top livestreamer had been set up
> by competitors to take a political fall, and perhaps the cake was sneaked into
> the line-up of his show on Friday. A clip circulating on social media,
> apparently of the moment before the cake is brought out, also shows Li
> expressing surprise over the announcement of a tank product. A male assistant
> announces in the background that the team has a tank-shaped good to sell. Li
> laughs and says: “What? A tank?” His co-presenter then says: “Let’s see if Li
> Jiaqi and I will still be here at 11pm.” They were taken off air shortly after
> 9pm.

Many fans suspect purposeful sabotage; perhaps that is a conspiracy theory, but
said theory is undergirded by the reality that it is not just possible but even
probable that a 30 year-old in China has no idea that selling a tank-shaped cake
on June 3rd is grounds for being disappeared. To put it another way, China’s
control of information is not unlike its control of COVID: it seems impossible,
and the means intolerable, but that is simply because we in the West can’t
imagine the limitations on personal freedom necessary to make it viable.

ACCEPTANCE AND COMPETITION

To further expand on this point: if people in the West would not accept truly
strict lockdowns, then they certainly wouldn’t accept centralized quarantine
(which didn’t work), which means they absolutely wouldn’t accept forced testing
and the inability to leave your house for months. Ergo, people in the West would
never accept the reality of zero-COVID, which is why it makes sense to go in the
opposite direction: open up, and forgo the massive costs of zero-COVID as well.
Don’t get stuck in the middle, enduring the worst outcomes of both.

Similarly, if people in the U.S. would not accept any government infringement on
speech, then they certainly wouldn’t accept ISP-level censorship like the Great
Firewall, which means they absolutely wouldn’t accept forced disappearances for
selling the wrong cake. Ergo, people in the U.S. would never accept the reality
of true control of speech, which is why it makes sense to go in the opposite
direction: embrace free speech not just as a law but as a cultural more, and
forgo the massive costs of half-ass speech restrictions as well. Don’t get stuck
in the middle, enduring the worst outcomes of both.

COVID, alas, seems to have been a worst case scenario in terms of both points:
we suffered the aforementioned economic, socio-political, and development damage
associated with strict control, while controlling nothing; meanwhile private
platforms went overboard in controlling information, and ended up only deepening
the suspicion of skeptics about COVID and its vaccines, leading to many more
deaths, but also increased skepticism about vaccines generally.

The worry is that this middling approach, where we get the worst of both worlds,
impacts innovation generally; China is increasingly focused on a top-down
approach to technological innovation in particular, placing heavy emphasis and
tons of money on catching up in areas like semiconductors and AI. The best
response is to go in the opposite direction, and let a thousand flowers bloom,
trusting that innovation by definition arises in places we least expect it.

To put it another way, if we could accurately eliminate bad ideas, then there
would, by definition, be no more good ideas to discover; the way to compete with
China is to lean into the fact that there remains so much we don’t yet know.

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

You likely have, by this point, heard the story of Katalin Karikó; from Stat
News in 2020:

> Before messenger RNA was a multibillion-dollar idea, it was a scientific
> backwater. And for the Hungarian-born scientist behind a key mRNA discovery,
> it was a career dead-end. Katalin Karikó spent the 1990s collecting
> rejections. Her work, attempting to harness the power of mRNA to fight
> disease, was too far-fetched for government grants, corporate funding, and
> even support from her own colleagues…By 1995, after six years on the faculty
> at the University of Pennsylvania, Karikó got demoted. She had been on the
> path to full professorship, but with no money coming in to support her work on
> mRNA, her bosses saw no point in pressing on.

Karikó would eventually figure out how to stop the body from rejecting mRNA, an
essential discovery on the way to today’s vaccines. Along the way, though, she
was nearly defeated by an academic system that increasingly relies on money from
the powers that be, who think they know everything; fortunately said powers
couldn’t actually stop her work, even though the consensus was that said work
was a bad idea.

Only with time did it reveal itself as a good idea, which is the story of almost
everything in life: we live, we learn, we discover new things, not just those of
us alive in 2022, but all of humanity for our entire existence. That is how we
beat COVID: not by destroying our liberties and lives, but by invention and
information. It turns out that free speech isn’t just an analogy to COVID: it’s
an essential part of getting past it. And, critically, it’s the only approach
that nearly all of us reading this article — particularly those of us in the
U.S., no matter our political affiliation — would actually tolerate.

In short, we live in the U.S., not China, and it’s high time all of us —
including tech companies — started acting like it, instead of LARPing the most
pathetic imitation possible.

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

 1. This case rate is likely significantly underreported, I would add: given
    that positive cases are not allowed to leave their house for 7 days — again,
    tracked by cellphone — there is a very strong incentive to simply not report
    a positive case; anecdotally speaking the majority of people I know in
    Taiwan have gotten COVID over the last month or so. 

 2. My aforementioned 18-day quarantine in April certainly seemed like a
    needless waste of my life — as do ongoing traveler quarantines whose only
    purpose is to protect travelers from what is again, the highest case rate in
    the world. 

 3. I do recognize that people wished to wait for a children’s vaccine; given
    the relative risk for children I disagreed, but I acknowledge the argument 


THIN PLATFORMS

Posted onTuesday, May 31, 2022Saturday, June 4, 2022

The Department of Justice’s 1998 complaint against Microsoft accused the company
of, amongst other things, tying the Internet Explorer browser to the Windows
operating system:

> Internet browsers are separate products competing in a separate product market
> from PC operating systems, and it is efficient to supply the two products
> separately. Indeed, Microsoft itself has consistently offered, promoted, and
> distributed its Internet browser as a stand-alone product separate from, and
> not as a component of, Windows, and intends to continue to do so after the
> release of Windows 98…
> 
> Microsoft’s tying of its Internet browser to its monopoly operating system
> reduces the ability of customers to choose among competing browser products
> because it forces OEMs and other purchasers to license or acquire the tied
> combination whether they want Microsoft’s Internet browser or not. Microsoft’s
> tying — which it can accomplish because of its monopoly power in Windows —
> impairs the ability of its browser rivals to compete to have their browsers
> preinstalled by OEMs on new PCs and thus substantially forecloses those rivals
> from an important channel of browser distribution.

In retrospect, the complaint feels quaint for three reasons:

First, Microsoft won the browser wars, and it didn’t matter; after peaking at
95% market share in 2004, Internet Explorer was first challenged by Firefox,
which peaked at 32% market share in 2010, and then surpassed by Chrome in 2012:



The reasons ended up being both a condemnation and an endorsement of the
libertarian defense of Microsoft’s actions, depending on your timeframe: sure,
the company leveraged its operating system dominance to gain browser market
share, but the company also made a great browser (I personally switched with the
release of version 4). And then, with Version 6 and its position seemingly
secured, the company just stopped development; that is what opened the door to
first Firefox and then Chrome, both of which were downloaded and installed by
end users looking for something better. The market worked, eventually.

Of course, the reason the market could work is that Windows was an open
platform: sure, Microsoft controlled (and allegedly abused) what could be
preinstalled on a new computer, but once said computer was in a user’s hands
they could install whatever they wanted to, including alternative browsers. That
gets to the second reason why the complaint feels quaint: today having a browser
pre-installed is de rigueur for operating systems, and Apple’s iOS goes much
further than simply pre-installing Safari: all alternative browsers must use
Apple’s built-in rendering engine, which means they can only compete on user
interface features, not fundamental functionality.


1



The third reason has to do with Microsoft itself.

THICK AND THIN

As I noted last week in an Update, one of the overarching themes of CEO Satya
Nadella’s Build developer conference keynote was the seemingly eternal tech
debate about thin versus thick clients (to dramatically simplify — and run the
risk of starting a flame war — thin clients are terminals for a centralized
computer, while thick clients are computers in their own right, that sync):

> The biggest takeaway from this keynote is that for developers, at least the
> ones that Microsoft is courting, the thin client model has won — although the
> truth, as is so often the case with tech holy wars, has ended up somewhere in
> the middle. Here is the key distinction: there is and will continue to be a
> lot of work that happens locally; all of the assumptions around that work,
> though, will be as if the work is being done on the server. For example:
> 
>  * GitHub Codespaces is an explicitly online environment that you can
>    temporarily use locally.
>  * Azure Arc provides the the Azure control plane for an on-premises
>    development environment.
>  * The Azure Container Apps service and Azure Kubernetes Service enable
>    developers to write locally in the same environment they deploy to the
>    cloud.
> 
> Moreover, several other of the announcements were about patching up
> limitations in cloud development relative to local: Microsoft Dev Box, for
> example, enables the deployment of cloud-based VMs that mimic a local
> development environment for things like app development; Microsoft Cloud PC
> (which was previously announced) does the same thing for client applications.

What makes this shift so striking is that it is being articulated by Microsoft;
after all, Windows (along with Intel) was the dominant winner of the thick
client era. Yes, Windows Server was an integral part of Microsoft’s enterprise
dominance, but the foundation of the company’s strategy — as evidenced by the
tactics used in the fight against Netscape — was the fact that Windows was the
operating system on the devices people used. That, by extension, was precisely
why mobile was so disruptive to the company: suddenly Windows was only on some
of the devices people used; iOS and Android were on a whole bunch of them as
well.

I’ve spent many articles writing about how Satya Nadella weaned Microsoft off of
its Windows-centric strategy; the pertinent point in terms of this Article comes
from Teams OS and the Slack Social Network:

> The end of Windows as the center of Microsoft’s approach, and the shift to the
> cloud, though, did not mean the end of Microsoft’s focus on integration, or
> its attempt to be an operating system; the company simply changed its
> definition of what an operating system was; Satya Nadella said at a press
> briefing in 2019:
> 
> > The other effort for us is what we describe as Microsoft 365. What we are
> > trying to do is bring home that notion that it’s about the user, the user is
> > going to have relationships with other users and other people, they’re going
> > to have a bunch of artifacts, their schedules, their projects, their
> > documents, many other things, their to-do’s, and they are going to use a
> > variety of different devices. That’s what Microsoft 365 is all about.
> > 
> > Sometimes I think the new OS is not going to start from the hardware,
> > because the classic OS definition, that Tanenbaum, one of the guys who
> > wrote the book on Operating Systems that I read when I went to school was:
> > “It does two things, it abstracts hardware, and it creates an app model”.
> > Right now the abstraction of hardware has to start by abstracting all of the
> > hardware in your life, so the notion that this is one device is interesting
> > and important, it doesn’t mean the kernel that boots your device just goes
> > away, it still exists, but the point of real relevance I think in our lives
> > is “hey, what’s that abstraction of all the hardware in my life that I use?”
> > – some of it is shared, some of it is personal. And then, what’s the app
> > model for it? How do I write an experience that transcends all of that
> > hardware? And that’s really what our pursuit of Microsoft 365 is all about.
> 
> This is where Teams thrives: if you fully commit to the Microsoft ecosystem,
> one app combines your contacts, conversations, phone calls, access to files,
> 3rd-party applications, in a way that “just works”…This is what Slack — and
> Silicon Valley, generally — failed to understand about Microsoft’s competitive
> advantage: the company doesn’t win just because it bundles, or because it has
> a superior ground game. By virtue of doing everything, even if mediocrely, the
> company is providing a whole that is greater than the sum of its parts,
> particularly for the non-tech workers that are in fact most of the market.
> Slack may have infused its chat client with love, but chatting is a means to
> an end, and Microsoft often seems like the only enterprise company that
> understands that.

Note that line about “3rd-party applications”: if Teams is the Windows of
Microsoft’s new services strategy, then it follows that the platform opportunity
for developers in Microsoft’s ecosystem is itself centered on Teams; that’s
exactly what Nadella described in the Build keynote:



> Let’s talk about the future of work and how we’re making apps more contextual
> and people-centric, so you can build a new class of collaborative
> applications. It starts with Microsoft Graph, which underlies Microsoft 365
> and makes available to you information about people, their relationships, and
> all of their artifacts. Today we are seeing developers around the world
> enriching their apps with Microsoft Graph. In fact, more than half of the
> Microsoft 365 tenant are using custom-built and 3rd-party apps powered by the
> Graph. With Graph connectors ISVs can extend their applications and have them
> be discovered as part of the user’s everyday tasks, whether they are writing
> an email, meeting on Teams, or doing a search. For example, data from an app
> can appear directly in an organization’s search results, as you can see in the
> experience Figma is building here. You can compose a mail and @-mention files
> from these apps in-line, and you can access them in Teams chat too. Another
> way that you can create interactive experiences is by building live actionable
> loop component using adaptive cards like partner Zoho does. Your users can
> make decisions and take action like updating the status of a ticket right in
> the flow of work, and updates are always live, like this one across Outlook,
> Teams, and Zoho.
> 
> When you combine the Microsoft Graph with Microsoft Teams, you combine the
> data that describes how people work together with the place they work
> together. It’s incredibly powerful, and developers are extending their apps
> into Teams and embedding Teams in their apps. In fact, monthly usage of
> 3rd-party apps and custom-built solutions on Teams has grown 10x over the last
> two years, and more and more ISVs are generating millions of [dollars in]
> revenue from customers using apps built on Teams.

“Graph connectors” are the new APIs.

WINDOWS VERSUS TEAMS

If the Windows platform looked like this…



…then the new Teams platform looks like this:



There are a few important observations to make about these differences.

First, in the PC era the monopoly that mattered was being the only operating
system on a single device. This, to be clear, is a technical necessity — while a
PC could dual-boot into different operating systems, only one could run at a
time


2 — but it was the foundation of Windows’ market monopoly. After all, whichever
operating system was running on the most devices most of the time was the
operating system that developers would target; the more developers on a
particular operating system, the more popular that operating system would be
amongst end users, resulting in a virtuous cycle, aka a two-sided network, aka
lock-in, aka a monopoly.



Once mobile came along, though, not only did the number of devices proliferate,
but so did the need for new user interfaces, power requirements, hardware
re-imagining, etc.; this made it inevitable that Microsoft would miss mobile,
because the company was approaching the problem from the completely wrong
perspective.


3 At the same time, this proliferation of devices meant that the point of
integration — which enterprises still craved — moved up the stack. I wrote in
2015’s Redmond and Reality:

4



> That is because there is in fact a need for an integrated solution on mobile.
> Look at Box, for example: the company obviously has a cloud component, but
> they also have multiple apps for every relevant — and non-relevant! — platform
> resulting in much better functionality than what Microsoft previously had to
> offer. Multiply that advantage across a whole host of services and it starts
> to make sense for the CIO to modularize her backend services in order to
> achieve integration when it comes to how those services are accessed:

This is exactly what Microsoft would go on to build with Teams: the beautiful
thing about chat is that like any social product it is only as useful as the
number of people who are using it, which is to say it only works if it is a
monopoly — everyone in the company needs to be on board, and they need to not be
using anything else. That, by extension, sets up Teams to play the Windows role,
but instead of monopolizing an individual PC, it monopolizes an entire company.

Second, developers had much more power and flexibility in the old model, because
they had direct access to the underlying PC. This had both advantages — anyone
could make an app that could do anything, and users could install it directly
— and disadvantages — anyone could make an app that could do anything, and users
could install it directly. In other words, the same openness of the PC that
presented an opportunity for Firefox and Chrome to dethrone Internet Explorer —
and for Netscape to exist in the first place — also presented an opportunity for
viruses, malware, and ransomeware.

This latter point is the justification that Apple returns to repeatedly for its
App Store model, even though a significant portion of the increased security of
mobile devices is due to fundamentally different architectural choices made in
designing the underlying operating system. Then again, these arguments go
hand-in-hand: it’s those architectural choices in iOS (and Android) design that
make App Store control possible; the broader point is that mobile set the
expectation that developer freedom — and by extension, opportunity — would be
limited by the operating system owner.

A thin platform like Teams takes this even further, because now developers don’t
even have access to the devices, at least in a way that matters to an enterprise
(i.e. how useful is an app on your phone that doesn’t connect to the company’s
directory, file storage, network, etc.). That means the question isn’t about
what system APIs are ruled to be off-limits, but what “connectors” (to use
Microsoft’s term) the platform owner deigns to build. In other words, not only
did Microsoft build their new operating system as a thin platform, they ended up
with far more control than they ever could have achieved with their old thick
platform.

STRIPE OS

Build wasn’t the only developer conference last week: Stripe also held Stripe
Sessions, and one of the tentpole sections of the keynote was called “Finance
OS”. Here’s Stripe co-founder and President John Collison:



> We’ve talked about payments, and how they’re highly strategic, and rapidly
> fragmenting, and we’ve talked about the business model innovations of adaptive
> enterprises and fintech everywhere. These trends are great news for the
> Internet economy, but a challenge for finance and business operations teams.
> The rate limiter for so many new opportunities isn’t the idea for a great
> product; it’s the mundane foundations. “Can we build for this? Can we get
> international operations off of the ground? Can we expand when we’re still not
> closing our books on time?” It’s never just about having the idea for a great
> product, it’s about being able to operate it, and that’s why we’re building a
> modern operating system for finance, and like any good OS, we’re focused on
> nailing the basics.

Those basics included features like invoicing, billing, taxes, revenue
recognition, and data pipelines, all of which sit on top of the various ways to
gather, store, and distribute money that Stripe has abstracted away:



This image, given its similarity to the one above, makes clear what was coming
next:



> So we just heard about core revenue management capabilities, like invoicing,
> subscription billing, and handling tax. Even if you’re not using Stripe, these
> are the things you should want running like clockwork.
> 
> But what about everything else? It’s like any operating system: core
> functionality needs to work perfectly out of the box, but the breadth of
> functionality of the platform is also really important, having an app to solve
> every use case. For things like customer messaging, you might want to use
> something like Intercom; for contracts, DocuSign; or, you might just to build
> your own tool. But often these workflows are highly integrated, so for years
> our users have been asking us for the tools of their choice to interoperate
> with Stripe…
> 
> We’re thrilled to launch today Stripe Apps and the Stripe App Marketplace,
> where you can find or build best-of-breed tools that work naturally with
> Stripe.

There are the missing pieces!



“Working naturally with Stripe” doesn’t simply mean access to Stripe’s APIs; it
means fitting in to the Stripe dashboard — Stripe is even including pre-made UI
components so that 3rd-party apps look like they were designed by the fintech
company:



This is another thin platform: developers don’t have access to the core
financial data of a company, nor does IT want them to; instead the opportunity
is to sit on top of an abstraction layer that covers all of a company’s
money-moving pieces, and to fit in as best as you can.

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Of course I am covering the Build and Stripe Sessions keynotes together because
both happened the same week; at the same time, it was a fortuitous coincidence,
because Stripe’s announcement brings important context to Microsoft’s approach.
After all, I used the magic word “monopoly”; the truth, though, is that not only
was an operating system monopoly inevitable, it also made perfect sense from a
user perspective that important functionality — like browsing — became
integrated with the core OS.

Collison made the case as to why similar considerations should be
front-and-center for thin platforms — there are things “you should want running
like clockwork.” Microsoft would make a similar argument about Teams and its
incorporation of things like file storage and communications, and, I would
argue, Teams’ success in the market relative to Slack is evidence that the
argument is a compelling one to customers. That Microsoft has so often seemed
like the only enterprise company actually building for an enterprise’s ends,
instead of solipsistically obsessing over being best-of-breed for one specific
means, seems worth celebrating and emulating, not condemning and complaining.

At the same time, it is also worth mourning the slow eclipse of the thick client
model. Yes, things like malware were a pain and a drain on productivity, and the
SaaS model has led to a plethora of new products that are accessible to
companies without needing an IT department, but the big downside of the thick
model in terms of what could go wrong and the necessity of IT created the
conditions for massive upside, in this case the opportunity to make new apps —
and by extension, new companies — without needing any permission, “connectors”
or pre-made UI components. Alas, the tech industry is past the end of the
beginning; welcome to middle age, where the only thickness is your waistline.

I wrote a follow-up to this Article in this Daily Update.

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

 1. Apple argues, not without merit, that this is for security reasons; critics
    argue, with considerable | merit, that this restricts innovation on iOS and
    meaningful competition with the App Store. 

 2. Absent virtualization, although that wasn’t really feasible on user-level
    PCs at the time Windows was establishing its dominance 

 3. This interview with Tony Fadell includes an excellent discussion on this
    point in the context of Intel, which applies just as much to Microsoft. 

 4. With, I am ashamed to admit, probably the worst drawing in the history of
    Stratechery; as I recall I was late to a Chinese New Years’ Eve dinner! 


WARNER BROS. DISCOVERY

Posted onMonday, May 23, 2022Monday, May 23, 2022

Last week the Wall Street Journal ran a profile of longtime Discovery CEO (now
Warner Bros. Discovery CEO) David Zaslav entitled There’s a New Media Mogul
Tearing Up Hollywood, adding “Zas Is Not Particularly Patient”. After opening
with an anecdote about Zaslav complaining about Warner Bros. backing a Clint
Eastwood movie, even though they thought it would fail, the profile states:

> Mr. Zaslav, who last month took over the company resulting from Discovery’s
> merger with AT&T Inc.’s WarnerMedia, has given every indication he wants to be
> a talent-friendly mogul, schmoozing with industry personalities at the Beverly
> Hills Hotel. But the 62-year-old cable-industry veteran, a protégé of the late
> Jack Welch, longtime CEO of General Electric Co., has shown he isn’t afraid to
> ruffle the industry’s elite.
> 
> He and his team have been scouring the company’s books, making it clear
> spending needs to be reined in. They have abandoned projects they consider
> costly and unnecessary. That included pulling the plug on CNN+, barely a month
> after previous management launched the streaming service, and canceling a DC
> Comics superhero movie in development. He has given an unwelcome jolt to
> executives in the WarnerMedia empire who were happy when AT&T decided to part
> with it in the merger, hoping there would be less financial scrutiny—not more…
> 
> Mr. Zaslav has few options other than drastic moves. The deal brought the new
> company—now home of Warner Bros. and cable channels including HBO, CNN, TNT,
> Food Network and HGTV—$55 billion in debt, and he has promised to cut at least
> $3 billion in costs. He has given executives a few weeks to provide
> restructuring and business plans. “We are not trying to win the
> direct-to-consumer spending war,” Mr. Zaslav said on an April earnings call.
> On the call, Chief Financial Officer Gunnar Wiedenfels called out the nearly
> $30 billion the company spends making and marketing content, saying: “We
> intend to drive the highest level of financial discipline here.”

The profile continued in the same vein, and came across as fairly negative; that
is why I appreciated it, because I am otherwise extremely bullish about the
potential for Zaslav’s new company.

HBO AND DISCOVERY SYNERGIES

I wrote a year ago when the deal between AT&T and Discovery was announced that
Warner Bros. and Discovery had excellent synergies:

> Start with the cable bundle: yes, cord-cutting continues, but there are still
> a lot of households with cable, and this new company will have significantly
> enhanced bargaining power with distributors. WarnerMedia’s combination of live
> sports, news, premium television, and scripted shows was already quite strong;
> Discovery brings a highly differentiated set of channels from HGTV to
> Discovery to Food Network that not only attract distinct demographics, but
> also are particularly effective at driving advertising.
> 
> Another set of synergies come in the two companies burgeoning
> direct-to-consumer offerings. Once again the breadth of content is a good
> thing: HBO Max and Discovery+ have something for everyone in the household.
> The types of content are complementary as well; back in 2018 I explained in
> the context of Friends:
> 
> > While most of the Netflix attention is paid to original series, the truth is
> > that there are two types of shows on the streaming network:
> > 
> >  * Original series drive new subscribers
> >  * “Filler”, that is, content that is there when subscribers simply want
> >    something to watch, keeps people subscribed
> 
> Discovery content is excellent filler [while HBO excels at original series].

Zaslav and CFO Gunnar Wiedenfels made all of these points on Warner Bros.
Discovery’s inaugural earnings call in late April. Start with the second point
above, about streaming synergy. Zaslav, in response to a question about
advertising (more on this in a moment), brought up the fact that Discovery+ has
very low churn:

> We’re in the market already with an ad-light product. We’re the ones that were
> out there very early saying ad-light looks really compelling, because it’s a
> great consumer proposition. Our users, the churn was very low; we were doing
> between two and four minutes of advertising and generating $5, $6 in
> incremental revenue, and as it scaled, we started to make more. And so, we
> said very early on, we’re going to switch to offer consumers what they want, a
> lower-priced opportunity with a small number of advertising.

HBO Max isn’t doing so well in this regard, at least according to Zaslav a few
minutes later:

> We have some work to do on the platform itself that will be significant. But
> we also think that one of the big opportunities here is going to be churn
> reduction. There is meaningful churn on HBO Max, much higher than the churn
> that we have seen. And so, the ability for us to come together is part of one
> of the thesis here that managing churn, and we’ve seen this because we’ve been
> added in Europe for eight years, as we begin to manage churn in a meaningful
> way, that provides a real meaningful growth.

The benefit of coming together is exactly what I noted a couple of years ago:
hits may capture customers, but filler content — especially a wide range of it —
keeps them:

> What you need is a diversity of content for everybody in the home, and they
> may come in for Euphoria [from HBO], but our research shows that people watch
> Euphoria, their favorite second show to watch is 90 Day Fiance [from TLC].
> Having a diversity of content is a reason why people are spending hours with
> Discovery+…when you put all of this diversity of content together, there is
> content for kids, there is content for teens, it’s basically everybody in the
> family, why would you go anywhere else. We have all the movies, we have all of
> the library content that you want…
> 
> If you look at HBO right now, what it really needs is precisely what we have.
> When they are finished with watching Winning Time, they can go and watch
> Friends or watch Big Bang or watch their favorite movie or go over and watch
> Oprah or watch some TLC shows just for fun. So, we believe and we see this in
> Europe where we tried to offer, we thought that the answer was just to offer
> niche high quality that you get high-quality shock and all content together
> with a lot of nutrition, in our case in Europe, together with sport and you
> offer something that everybody in the family uses, and the churn goes way
> down, it’s much harder to churn out of a product when your kids use it or your
> significant other uses it or your mom and dad are watching, but also if you
> find yourself watching it more often. So, I think it’s precisely why we did
> this deal. And I think everything tells us that it’s going to make us stronger
> and more compelling because of the breadth of the quality menu of IP that we
> have.

In short, HBO Max plus Discovery+ is a bundle, with all of the attendant
advantages that entails (and which certainly did not apply to a standalone CNN+
service). Of course this also strengthens Warner Bros. Discovery’s hand in terms
of the linear TV bundle as well; Zaslav said in his prepared remarks:

> One of the company’s unique assets is the linear network group, and in 2021
> taken together, we enjoyed the number one share in total television total day
> in all key demos and people 2+. And we have the greatest brands: HG, Food,
> HBO, Discovery, CNN, NBA, March Madness, NHL, Magnolia, The Oprah Winfrey
> Network. Our balanced verticals and content genres across scripted, lifestyle,
> sports and news provide us with significant opportunities to not only
> cross-promote for the benefit of the portfolio, but also to offer compelling
> reach and targeting campaigns for our advertising partners.

Don’t forget negotiating leverage; Wiedenfels noted:

> US distribution revenues were up 11% year-over-year, largely driven by the
> growth of Discovery+ subscribers throughout 2021, while linear affiliate
> revenues were also up year-over-year as rate increases continued to outpace
> subscriber declines. Our fully distributed subscribers were down 4% as were
> total portfolio subscribers when correcting for the impact of the sale of our
> Great American Country network in early June last year.

Yes, cords are still being cut, especially last year, but the story of cable for
the last several years has been the jettisoning of cost-driven subscribers in
favor of charging full price for people who actually want linear TV, which, in
the long run, means that the linear TV bundle is primarily the sports and news
bundle. Warner Bros. is well-placed for this new world, thanks to its
combination of sports rights on TNT and TBS, along with CNN. That, though, isn’t
a guarantee of profitability; Zaslav noted in an answer explaining why news was
more profitable than sports:

> When it comes to sports, we’re very careful about sports. And the TNT and
> Warner team was clever about getting long term rights which we’re going to get
> a lot of benefit from, but sports are rented and news is scalable.

The unscripted content that Discovery specializes in is even more scalable, and
far cheaper; now, instead of negotiating with cable providers like Comcast for a
collection of channels that customers like, but don’t necessarily need
(particularly since Discovery+ is an option), Warner Bros. Discovery will be
negotiating for a bundle that includes sports and news and filler. Those sports
rights may eat up a lot of TNT and TBS’s carriage fees; the real money will be
made on the extra pennies added to the rest of the channels in the portfolio.

And then, of course, that money can be spent on streaming: sure, Netflix has the
advantage of having a larger customer base, but no one — other than Netflix
executives until a month ago — said that you could only use subscription dollars
and nothing else to acquire streaming content.

ADVERTISING’S CONTINUED STRENGTH

Then there is advertising. First — and in contrast to Netflix’s agonizing on the
matter — I enjoyed how matter-of-fact Zaslav was about having ad-supported
streaming tiers:

> In streaming, we have a massive opportunity to reach the widest possible
> addressable market by offering a range of tiers, all with the most compelling
> and complete portfolio of content. A premium and attractively priced ad-free
> direct-to-consumer product, a lower-priced ad-light tier, something we have
> had tremendous success with and is our highest ARPU product, and in some very
> price-sensitive markets outside the United States, we can even offer an
> advertiser-only product.

Secondly, Warner Bros. Discovery can provide a one-stop shop for advertisers
across streaming and TV; Zaslav said in his opening remarks:

> The combined strengths of both organizations’ client relationships, advanced
> advertising, programmatic, sponsorships and direct-to-consumer, ad-light
> streaming services, all positioned the company with a unique hand. I’ve
> personally spent quite a bit of time with key advertisers and agencies, and
> I’m so impressed with the combined capability of our platforms and our ability
> to uniquely serve the needs of our clients, including integrating sports
> alongside our broad entertainment offerings.

The bit about integrating sports refers to the fact that Warner Bros. actually
had multiple advertising teams (one for sports and one for everything else — but
none for streaming); I’m not entirely clear how the company ended up in this
position, but given the fact the company’s businesses were built in an era where
ad agencies sat in the middle between advertisers on one side and inventory on
the other, it makes a certain sort of sense. Today, though, the goal is to be as
large and as integrated as possible, the better to share data and provide
effective targeting at scale; that offering is particularly compelling given
that streaming is the best place to reach all of those people that cut the cord.

Still, even with the cord-cutting, TV advertising continues to be a good
business; Zaslav reflected:

> We recognize that 4% of subscribers are down and viewership on the platform is
> down…Long-term, there’s no question that the business is challenging, but CPMs
> are increasing, advertisers still are looking for inventory, because it’s the
> most effective inventory in long-form video. And look, remember, broadcast for
> a period of 20 years was declining and CPMs were increasing. I was at NBC in
> the mid-’90s when Welsh was saying this can’t continue. We can’t have smaller
> and smaller audiences and make more and more money. And I think he was right
> or maybe he will be right eventually, but it’s almost 30 years later and the
> advertisers are still paying more than the hurdle rate of decline.
> 
> So, we will be leaning in with efficiencies and effectiveness to our
> traditional business, which generates an awful lot of free cash flow…We now
> have the same or in many cases, the largest reach on television in the US. And
> the ability to use our own inventory to promote to and from all of our
> products and the efficiency of doing that and the cost savings of doing it, I
> think is a big plus for us.

There are a few things going on here, and both go back to an Article I wrote in
2016 called TV Advertising’s Surprising Strength — and Inevitable Fall. The key
insight in that piece was that huge swathes of the economy, from large CPG
companies to big box retailed to auto makers, were all built around TV
advertising, which meant they would prop up the medium far longer than people
thought:

> Brands uniquely suited to TV are probably by definition less suited to digital
> advertising, which at least to date has worked much better for direct response
> marketing. No one is going to click a link in their feed to buy a car or
> laundry detergent, and a brick-and-mortar retailer doesn’t want to encourage
> shopping to someone already online. So after a bit of experimentation, they’re
> back with TV.
> 
> Still, I think Facebook and Snapchat in particular will figure brand
> advertising out: both have incredibly immersive advertising formats, and both
> are investing in ways to bring direct response-style tracking to brand
> advertising, including tracking visits to brick-and-mortar retailers.

Six years on, and “Surprising Strength” remains correct, while “Inevitable Fall”
is the prediction that is looking shakier: to the extent that brand advertising
is going digital, a lot of the shift seems to be doing so primarily as streaming
video ads, a shift that will only accelerate as Netflix, HBO Max, and Disney all
launch ad products. The most privacy-invasive practices of Facebook et al,
meanwhile, have been curtailed (and rightly so — products that cross over into
real-world tracking are where I have always drawn a hard line).

Just as important, though, are the impact of changes like ATT on the small and
medium-sized businesses that were threatening the biggest advertisers like a
hundred duck-sized horses: by destroying their ability to effectively coordinate
their advertising spend, ATT and similar regulations have breathed new life into
the old ecosystem, which ultimately plays to the benefit of the largest
advertising sellers, including Warner Bros. Discovery.

REASONS FOR OPTIMISM

Like I said, I’m pretty optimistic about Warner Bros. Discovery, which is why I
appreciated the Wall Street Journal article I opened with: it’s fair to wonder
if the exact sort of clarity of thinking and explicit commitment to financial
results that Zaslav demonstrated on that earnings call will translate into
managing talent and navigating Hollywood, particularly given the huge debt load
the new company is carrying.

That noted, the other reason to be bullish is that Warner Bros. Discovery’s
strategy is, in contrast to Netflix, back to the future; Zaslav said at the
beginning of the call:

> These last few months in our industry have been an important reminder that
> while technology will continue to empower consumers of video entertainment,
> the recipe for long-term success is still made up of a few key ingredients.
> Number one, world-class IP content that is loved all over the globe; two,
> distribution of that content on every platform and device where consumers want
> to engage, whether it’s theatrical or linear or streaming; three, a balanced
> monetization model that optimizes the value of what we create and drives
> diversified revenue streams; and four, finally, durable and sustainable free
> cash flow generation.

This isn’t anything new: the Hollywood model has always been about creating
compelling content once and then monetizing it through every possible means; in
Zaslav’s view a self-owned streaming platform is just an addition to the old
model, not a wholesale replacement.

Moreover, things like movies in theaters still have their advantages: they build
IP and build awareness for the other content models, above and beyond the money
they make. Oh, and to take this update full circle, they also make talent like
Eastwood happy. To that end, I suspect in the long run that flexibility and
pragmatism in content distribution, combined with real discipline about cash
flow, will prove to be more compelling than the same combination in reverse.


CABLE’S LAST LAUGH

Posted onTuesday, May 10, 2022Tuesday, May 10, 2022

If there is one industry people in tech are eternally certain is doomed, it is
cable. However, the reality is that cable is both stronger than ever and poised
for growth; the reasons why are instructive to not just tech industry observers,
but to tech companies themselves.

THE CREATION OF CABLE

Robert J. Tarlton was 29 years old, married with a son, when he volunteered to
fight in World War II; thanks to the fact he owned a shop in Lansford,
Pennsylvania that sold radios, he ended up repairing them all across the
European Theater, learning about not just reception but also transmission. After
the war Tarlton re-opened his shop, when Motorola, one of his primary suppliers,
came out with a new television.

Tarlton was intrigued, but he had a geography problem; the nearest television
station was in Philadelphia, 71 miles away; in the middle lie the Pocono
Mountains, and mountains aren’t good for reception:



It turned out, though, that some people living in Summit Hill, the next
community over, could get the Philadelphia broadcast signal; that’s where
Tarlton sold his first television sets. Of course Tarlton couldn’t demonstrate
this new-fangled contraption; his shop was in Lansford, not Summit Hill.
However, it was close to Summit Hill: what if Tarlton could place an antenna
further up the mountain in Summit Hill and run a cable to his shop? Tarlton
explained in an interview in 1986:

> Lansford is an elongated town. It’s about a mile and a half long and there are
> about eight parallel streets bisected with cross streets about every 500 feet.
> There are no curves; everything is all laid out in a nice symmetrical pattern.
> Our business place was about three streets from the edge of Summit Hill and
> Lansford sits on kind of a slope. The edge of Lansford inclines from about a
> thousand feet above sea level to about fifteen hundred feet above sea level in
> Summit Hill. So to get television into our store, my father and I put an
> antenna partly up the mountain. No, we didn’t go all the way up, but we put up
> an antenna, kind of a crude arrangement, and then from tree to tree we strung
> a twin lead that was used in those days as a transmission line. We ran this
> twin lead, crossed a few streets, and into our store. And we had television.

The basic twin lead was barely functional, but that didn’t stop everyone from
demanding a television with a haphazard wire to their house; Tarlton realized
that new coaxial cable amplifiers designed for a single property could be
chained together, re-amplifying the signal so it could reach multiple
properties. After getting all of the other electronics retailers on board
— Tarlton knew that a clear signal would sell more TV sets, but that everyone
needed to use the same system — the first commercial cable system was born, and
it sold itself. Tarlton reflected:

> You didn’t have to advertise. You had to keep your door locked because the
> people were clamoring for service. They wanted cable service. You certainly
> didn’t have to advertise.

People couldn’t get enough TV; Tarlton explained:

> Cable is dependent upon advances in technology because people who originally
> saw one channel wanted to see the second channel, wanted to see the third, and
> after you had five, they wanted more. So it was a case of more begets more. At
> one time three channels seemed to be quite sufficient but when we added one
> more channel, it created a new interest in the cable system. People then had
> variety. They had alternatives. At one time later five channels seemed enough.
> As a matter of fact, a man who is often quoted, former FCC Commissioner Ken
> Cox, said that five channels was enough, and that’s quite a story in itself.
> The engineers were able to continually refine equipment to add more
> channels…All these technical advances‑‑continuing advances, automatic gain
> control, automatic temperature compensation, etc. have made cable what it is
> today.

One of the most important technological developments was satellite: now cable
systems could get signals both more reliably and from far further away; this
actually flipped geography on its head. Tarlton said:

> At that time we went to the highest possible point to look to the transmitter.
> Today with satellites, we go to the lowest possible point because we don’t
> want the interference from other signals. So it is ironic that we have changed
> so much from what we used to do.

Within these snippets is everything that makes the cable business so compelling:

 * Cable is in high demand because it provides the means to get what customers
   most highly value.
 * Cable works best both technologically and financially when it has a
   geographic monopoly.
 * Cable creates demand for new supply; technological advances enable more
   supply, which creates more demand.

It’s that last bit about satellites being better on lower ground that stands out
to me, though: as long as you control the wires into people’s houses you can and
should be pragmatic about everything else.

CABLE’S EVOLUTION

Tarlton would go on to work for a company called Jerrold Electronics, which
pivoted its entire business to create equipment for cities that wanted to
emulate Lansford’s system; Tarlton would lead the installation of cable systems
across the United States, which for the first two decades of cable mostly
retransmitted broadcast television.

The aforementioned satellite, though, led to the creation of national TV
stations, first HBO, and then WTCG, an independent television station in
Atlanta, Georgia, owned by Ted Turner. Turner realized he could buy programming
at local rates, but sell advertising at national rates via cable operators eager
to feed their customers’ hunger for more stations. Turner soon launched a cable
only channel devoted to nothing but news; he called it the Cable News Network
— CNN for short (WTCG would later be renamed TBS).

Jerrold Electronics, meanwhile, spun off one of the cable systems it built in
Tupelo, Mississippi to an entrepreneur named Ralph Roberts; Roberts proceeded to
systematically buy up community cable systems across the country, moving the
company’s headquarters to Philadelphia and renaming it to Comcast Corporation
(Roberts would eventually hand the business off to his son, Brian).
Consolidation in the provision of cable service proceeded in conjunction with
consolidation in the production of content, an inevitable outcome of the
virtuous cycle I noted above:

 * Cable companies acquired customers who wanted access to content
 * Studios created content that customers demanded

The more customers that a cable company served, the stronger their negotiating
position with content providers; the more studios and types of content that a
content provider controlled the stronger their negotiating position with cable
providers. The end result were a few dominant cable providers (Comcast, Charter,
Cox, Altice, Mediacom) and a few dominant content companies (Disney, Viacom, NBC
Universal, Time Warner, Fox), tussling back-and-forth over a very profitable
pie.

Then came Netflix, and tech industry crowing about cord cutting.

Netflix and other streaming services were obviously bad for television: they did
the same job but in a completely different way, leveraging the Internet to
provide content on-demand, unconstrained by the linear nature of television that
was a relic of cable’s origin with broadcast TV. Here, though, cable’s ownership
of the wires was an effective hedge: the same wires that delivered linear TV
delivered packet-based Internet content.

Moreover, this didn’t simply mean that cable’s TV losses were made up for by
Internet service: Internet service was much higher margin because companies like
Comcast didn’t need to negotiate with a limited number of content providers;
everything on the Internet was free. This has meant that the fortunes of cable
companies has boomed over the last decade, even as cord-cutting has cut the
cable TV business by about a third.

Cable companies today, though, are yet another category down from their pandemic
highs, thanks to fear that the broadband growth story is mostly over; fiber
offers better performance, 5G opens the door to wireless in the home, and anyone
who doesn’t have broadband now is probably never going to get it. I think,
though, this underrates the strategic positioning of cable companies, and
ignores the industry’s demonstrated ability to adapt to new strategic
environments.

THE WIRELESS OPPORTUNITY

From the Wall Street Journal in 2011:

> Verizon Wireless will pay $3.6 billion to buy wireless spectrum licenses from
> a group of cable-television companies, bringing an end to their years-long
> flirtation with setting up its own cellphone service. The sellers—Comcast Time
> Warner Cable Inc. and Bright House Networks—acquired the spectrum in a
> government auction in 2006 and now will turn it over to the country’s biggest
> wireless carrier at more than a 50% markup. While cable companies have dabbled
> with wireless, the spectrum has largely sat around unused, prompting years of
> speculation about the industry’s intentions…
> 
> Under the deal, Verizon Wireless will be able to sell its service in the cable
> companies’ stores. The carrier, in turn, will be able to sell the cable
> companies’ broadband, video and voice services in its stores. Verizon’s FiOS
> service only reaches 14% of U.S. households, according to Bernstein Research.
> In four years’ time, the cable companies will have the option to buy service
> on Verizon’s network on a wholesale basis and then resell it under their own
> brand.
> 
> The joint marketing arrangement “amounts to a partnership between formerly
> mortal enemies,” wrote Bernstein analyst Craig Moffett in a research note.

Moffett would later partner with Michael Nathanson to form their own independent
research firm (called MoffettNathanson, natch); Moffett released an updated
report last month that explained how that Verizon deal ended up playing out:

> When Comcast and Time Warner Cable sold their AWS-1 spectrum to Verizon back
> in 2011, they believed at the time that they were walking away from ever
> becoming facilities-based wireless players. They therefore viewed it as
> imperative that the sale come with an MVNO agreement with Verizon to
> compensate for that forfeiture. They got precisely what they wanted, an MVNO
> contract with Verizon that was described at the time as “perpetual and
> irrevocable“…
> 
> It took another six years after that transaction before Comcast finally
> launched Xfinity Mobile in mid-2017. Charter [which merged with Time Warner
> Cable, acquiring the latter’s MVNO rights] followed suit a year later…in four
> short years, the Cable operators have become the fastest growing wireless
> providers in the country, accounting for nearly 30% of wireless industry net
> additions. Cable’s 7.7 million mobile lines represent ~2.5% of the U.S. mobile
> phone market (including prepaid and postpaid phones).

As Moffett notes, this growth is particularly impressive given that most cable
companies couldn’t feasibly offer family plans under the terms of the original
deal, which was negotiated before such a concept even existed; the deal has been
re-negotiated, though, and almost certainly to the cable companies’ advantage:
if Verizon is going to lose customers to an MVNO, it would surely prefer said
MVNO be on their network; this means that the cable companies have negotiating
leverage.

What, though, makes the cable companies such effective MVNOs? One of the most
interesting parts of Moffett’s note was proprietary data about the amount of
data used by cellular subscribers; it turns out that cable MVNO customers are
far more likely to consume data over WiFi, perhaps because of cable company
out-of-home WiFi hot spots. This could become even more favorable in the future
as cable companies build out Citizens Broadband Radio Service (CBRS) service,
particularly in dense areas where cable companies have wires from which to hang
CBRS transmitters. Moffett writes:

> In a perfect world, Cable will offload traffic onto their own facilities where
> doing so is cheap (high density, high use locations) and leave to Verizon the
> burden of carrying traffic where doing so is/would be expensive. Because the
> MVNO agreement is “perpetual and irrevocable,” and is based on average prices
> (i.e., the same price everywhere, whether easy or hard to reach), Cable is
> presented with a perfect ROI arbitrage; they can take the high ROI parts of
> the network for themselves, and leave the low ROI parts of the network to
> their MVNO host… all without sacrificing anything with respect to their
> national coverage footprint.

One can understand why Verizon gave the cable companies these rights in 2011;
the phone company desperately needed spectrum, and besides, everyone knew that
MVNOs could never be economically competitive with their wholesale providers,
who were the ones that actually made the investments in the network.

That’s the thing, though: cable companies had their own massive build-out, one
that was both much older in its origins and, because it connected the house,
actually carried more data. This was to the benefit of Verizon and other
cellular providers, of course: a Verizon iPhone uses WiFi at home just as much
as a Comcast iPhone does; here, though, it was cable that had internet economics
on its side: there is no competitive harm in giving equal access to an abundant
resource; it is cellular access that is scarce, which means that the cable
companies’ MVNO deal, in conjunction with their out-of-home Internet access
options, gives them a meaningful advantage.

CUSTOMER ACQUISITION

Moffett spends less time on customer acquisition; anecdotally speaking, it’s
clear that Charter’s Spectrum, which provides the cable service I consume (via
the excellent Channels application), is pushing wireless service hard: phones
are front-and-center in their stores, and Spectrum wireless commercials fill
local inventory. Moreover, this is a well-trodden playbook: cable companies came
to dominate the fixed line phone service business simply because it was easier
to get your TV, Internet, and phone all in the same place (and of those, the
most important was TV, and now Internet); it’s always easier to upsell an
existing subscriber than it is to acquire a new one.

Of course cable companies long handled customer acquisition for content creators
— that was the cable bundle in a nutshell. What is interesting is how this
customer acquisition capability is attractive to the companies undoing that
bundle: Netflix, for example, put its service on Comcast’s set-top boxes in
2016, and made a deal for Comcast to sell its service in 2018. I wrote in a
Daily Update at the time:

> Netflix, meanwhile, is laddering up again: the company doesn’t actually need a
> billing relationship with end users, it just needs ever more end users (along
> with the data about what they watch) to spread its fixed content costs more
> widely; the company said in its shareholder letter that:
> 
> > These relationships allow our partners to attract more customers and to
> > upsell existing subscribers to higher ARPU packages, while we benefit from
> > more reach, awareness and often, less friction in the signup and payment
> > process. We believe that the lower churn in these bundles offsets the lower
> > Netflix ASP.
> 
> What is particularly interesting is that this arrangement moves the industry
> closer to the endgame I predicted in The Great Unbundling…

“Endgame” was a bit strong: that Article was, as the title says, about
unbundling; one of my arguments was that the traditional cable TV bundle would
become primarily anchored on live sports and news, while most scripted content
went to streaming. That is very much the case today (TBS, for example, is
abandoning scripted content, while becoming ever more reliant on sports). What
was a mistake was insinuating that this was the “end”; after all, as Jim
Barksdale famously observed, the next step after unbundling is bundling.

To that end, Netflix + Xfinity TV service was a bundle of sorts, but the real
takeaway was that Comcast was fine with being simply an Internet provider (which
ended up helping with TV margins, since cable companies mostly gave up on
fighting to keep cord cutters). Shortly after the Netflix deal Comcast launched
Xfinity Flex, a free 4K streaming box for Internet-only subscribers that
included a storefront for buying streaming services (which would be billed by
Comcast). You can even subscribe to digital MVPDs like YouTube TV!



The first takeaway of an offering like Xfinity Flex ties into the wireless
point: cable companies already have a billing relationship with the customer —
because they provide the most essential utility for accessing what is most
important to said customer — which makes them particularly effective at customer
acquisition. That is why Netflix, YouTube, etc. are all willing to pay a revenue
share for the help.

THE GREAT REBUNDLING?

The second takeaway, though, is that the cable companies are better suited than
almost anyone else to rebundle for real. Imagine a “streaming bundle” that
includes Netflix, HBO Max, Disney+, Paramount+, Peacock, etc., available for a
price that is less than the sum of its parts. Sounds too good to be true, right?
After all, this kind of sounds like what Apple was envisioning for Apple TV (the
app) before Netflix spoiled the fun; I wrote in Apple Should Buy Netflix in
2016:

> Apple’s desire to be “the one place to access all of your television” implies
> the demotion of Netflix to just another content provider, right alongside its
> rival HBO and the far more desperate networks who lack any sort of customer
> relationship at all. It is directly counter to the strategy that has gotten
> Netflix this far — owning the customer relationship by delivering a superior
> customer experience — and while Apple may wish to pursue the same strategy,
> the company has no leverage to do so. Not only is the Apple TV just another
> black box that connects to your TV (that is also the most expensive), it also,
> conveniently for Netflix, has a (relatively) open app platform: Netflix can
> deliver their content on their terms on Apple’s hardware, and there isn’t much
> Apple can do about it.

Six years on and Netflix is in a much different place, not only struggling for
new customers but also dealing with elevated churn. Owning the customer may be
less important than simply having more customers, particularly if those
customers are much less likely to churn. After all, that’s one of the advantages
of a bundle: instead of your streaming service needing to produce compelling
content every single month, you can work as a team to keep customers on board
with the bundle.

The key point about a bundle, as longtime YouTube executive and Coda CEO Shishir
Mehrotra has written, is that it minimizes SuperFan overlap while maximizing
CasualFan overlap; in other words, effective bundles have more disparate content
that you are vaguely interested in, instead of a relatively small amount of
focused content that you care about intensely. This makes the bundle concept
even more compelling to new entrants in the streaming wars, who may not have as
large of libraries as Netflix, and certainly don’t have as many subscribers over
which to spread their content costs.

Moreover, the fact that the streaming services have largely done their damage to
traditional TV, leaving the cable TV bundle as the sports and news bundle, means
it is actually viable to create a lower-priced bundle than what was previously
available (if you don’t want sports). After all, you’re not cannibalizing TV,
but rather bringing together what has long since been broken off (unbundling
then bundling!).

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

This isn’t something that is going to happen overnight: despite the fact that
bundles are good for everyone it is hard to get independents into a bundle as
long as they are growing; Netflix’s recent struggles are encouraging in this
regard, particularly if other streaming services start to face similar
headwinds. Moreover, cable companies are not the only entities that will seek to
pull something like this off: Apple, Amazon, Google, and Roku already make money
from revenue shares on streaming subscriptions they sell; all of them sell
devices that can be used as interfaces for selling a bundle. And, of course,
there are more Internet providers than just the cable companies: there is fiber,
wireless, and even Starlink.

The breadth of the cable company bundle, though, is unmatched: not only might it
include streaming services, but also linear TV; more than that, this is the
company selling you Internet access, and increasingly wireless phone service.
That gives even more latitude for discounts, and perks like no data caps on
streamed content, not just at home but also on your phone.

All of these advantages go back to Robert J. Tarlton and Lansford, Pennsylvania.
A recurring point on Stratechery this past year has been the durability and
long-term potential inherent in technology rooted in physical space. I wrote in
Digital Advertising in 2022:

> Real power in technology comes from rooting the digital in something physical:
> for Amazon that is its fulfillment centers and logistics on the e-commerce
> side, and its data centers on the cloud side. For Microsoft it is its data
> centers and its global sales organization and multi-year relationships with
> basically every enterprise on earth. For Apple it is the iPhone, and for
> Google is is Android and its mutually beneficial relationship with Apple (this
> is less secure than Android, but that is why Google is paying an estimated $15
> billion annually — and growing — to keep its position). Facebook benefited
> tremendously from being just an app, but the freedom of movement that entailed
> meant taking a dependency on iOS and Android, and Apple has exploited that
> dependency in part, if not yet in full.

For cable companies, power comes from a wire; it would certainly be ironic if
the cord-cutting trumpeted by tech resulted in cable having even more leverage
over customers and their wallets than the pre-Internet era.


BEYOND AGGREGATION: AMAZON AS A SERVICE

Posted onMonday, April 25, 2022Monday, April 25, 2022

Five months and $134 billion in market cap ago (before the stock slipped by
68%), Bloomberg Businessweek purported to explain How Shopify Outfoxed Amazon to
Become the Everywhere Store. One of the key parts of the story was how Shopify
pulled one over on Amazon seven years ago:

> An even more critical event came a few months after the IPO. Amazon also
> operated a service that let independent merchants run their websites, called
> Webstore. Bang & Olufsen, Fruit of the Loom, and Lacoste were among the 80,000
> or so companies that used it to run their online shops. If he wanted to, Bezos
> surely had the resources and engineering prowess to crush Shopify and steal
> its momentum.
> 
> But Amazon execs from that time admit that the Webstore service wasn’t very
> good, and its sales were dwarfed by all the rich opportunities the company was
> seeing in its global marketplace, where customers shop on Amazon.com, not on
> merchant websites…In late 2015, in one of Bezos’ periodic purges of
> underachieving businesses, he agreed to close Webstore. Then, in a rare
> strategic mistake that’s likely to go down in the annals of corporate
> blunders, Amazon sent its customers to Shopify and proclaimed publicly that
> the Canadian company was its preferred partner for the Webstore diaspora. In
> exchange, Shopify agreed to offer Amazon Pay to its merchants and let them
> easily list their products on Amazon’s marketplace. Shopify also paid Amazon
> $1 million—a financial arrangement that’s never been previously reported.
> 
> Bezos and his colleagues believed that supporting small retailers and their
> online shops was never going to be a large, profitable business. They were
> wrong—small online retailers generated about $153 billion in sales in 2020,
> according to AMI Partners. “Shopify made us look like fools,” says the former
> Amazon executive.

If only we could all make such excellent mistakes; Amazon’s move looks like a
strategic masterstroke.

SHOPIFY’S REVENUE STREAMS

Three major things have changed, will change, or should change about Shopify’s
business in the years since the company made that deal with Amazon.

What has changed is the composition of Shopify’s business. While the company
started out with a SaaS model, the business has transformed into a
commission-based one:



“Subscription Solutions” are Shopify’s platform fees, including the cost to use
the platform (or upgrade to the company’s Pro offering), commissions from the
sales of themes and apps, and domain name registration. “Merchant Solutions”,
meanwhile, are all of the fees that are generated from ongoing sales; the
largest part of this are payment processing fees from Shopify Payments, but
other fees include advertising revenue, referral fees, Shopify Shipping, etc.

It’s the shipping part that is line for big changes: while Shopify first
announced the Shopify Fulfillment Network back in 2019, it is only recently that
the company has committed to actually building out important pieces of said
network on its own, the better to compete with Amazon’s full-scale offering.

As for what should change, I argued back in February that Shopify needed to
build out an advertising network; this recommendation is more pertinent than
ever, in large part because the second item on this list might be in big
trouble.

BUY WITH PRIME

From the Wall Street Journal:

> Amazon.com Inc. is extending some of the offerings of its popular Prime
> membership program to merchants off its platform with a new service that
> embeds the online retailing giant’s payment and fulfillment options onto
> third-party sites. Called Buy with Prime, the service will allow merchants to
> show the Prime logo and offer Amazon’s speedy delivery options on products
> listed on their own websites…
> 
> The company said the Buy with Prime offer will be rolled out by invitation
> only through 2022 for those who already sell on Amazon and use the company’s
> fulfillment services. Later, Amazon plans to extend Buy with Prime to other
> merchants, including those that don’t sell on its platform. Participating
> merchants will use the Prime logo and display expected delivery dates on
> eligible products. Checkout will go through Amazon Pay and the company’s
> fulfillment network. Amazon will also manage free returns for eligible orders.

This is a move that you could see coming for a long time; back in 2016 I wrote
an article called The Amazon Tax that explained that the best way to understand
Amazon as a whole was to understand Amazon Web Services (AWS):

> The “primitives” model modularized Amazon’s infrastructure, effectively
> transforming raw data center components into storage, computing, databases,
> etc. which could be used on an ad-hoc basis not only by Amazon’s internal
> teams but also outside developers:
> 
> 
> 
> This AWS layer in the middle has several key characteristics:
> 
>  * AWS has massive fixed costs but benefits tremendously from economies of
>    scale
>  * The cost to build AWS was justified because the first and best customer is
>    Amazon’s e-commerce business
>  * AWS’s focus on “primitives” meant it could be sold as-is to developers
>    beyond Amazon, increasing the returns to scale and, by extension, deepening
>    AWS’ moat
> 
> This last point was a win-win: developers would have access to
> enterprise-level computing resources with zero up-front investment; Amazon,
> meanwhile, would get that much more scale for a set of products for which they
> would be the first and best customer.

As I noted in that article, the AWS model was being increasingly applied to
e-commerce as Amazon shifted from being a retailer to being a services provider:

> Prime is a super experience with superior prices and superior selection, and
> it too feeds into a scale play. The result is a business that looks like this:
> 
> 
> 
> That is, of course, the same structure as AWS — and it shares similar
> characteristics:
> 
>  * E-commerce distribution has massive fixed costs but benefits tremendously
>    from economies of scale
>  * The cost to build-out Amazon’s fulfillment centers was justified because
>    the first and best customer is Amazon’s e-commerce business
>  * That last bullet point may seem odd, but in fact 40% of Amazon’s sales (on
>    a unit basis) are sold by 3rd-party merchants; most of these merchants
>    leverage Fulfilled-by-Amazon, which means their goods are stored in
>    Amazon’s fulfillment centers and covered by Prime. This increases the
>    return to scale for Amazon’s fulfillment centers, increases the value of
>    Prime, and deepens Amazon’s moat

My prediction in that Article was that Amazon’s burgeoning logistics business
would eventually follow the same path:

> It seems increasingly clear that Amazon intends to repeat the model when it
> comes to logistics…how might this play out? Well, start with the fact that
> Amazon itself would be this logistics network’s first-and-best customer, just
> as was the case with AWS. This justifies the massive expenditure necessary to
> build out a logistics network that competes with UPS, Fedex, et al, and most
> outlets are framing these moves as a way for Amazon to rein in shipping costs
> and improve reliability, especially around the holidays.
> 
> However, I think it is a mistake to think that Amazon will stop there: just as
> they have with AWS and e-commerce distribution I expect the company to offer
> its logistics network to third parties, which will increase the returns to
> scale, and, by extension, deepen Amazon’s eventual moat

Today Amazon’s logistics is massive and fully integrated from the fulfillment
center to the doorstep, even though it only serves Amazon; the obvious next step
is opening it up to non-Amazon retailers, and that is exactly what is happening.

BEYOND AGGREGATION

At first glance, this might seem like a bit of a surprise; after all,
Stratechery is well known for describing Aggregation Theory, which is predicated
on controlling demand. In the case of Amazon that has meant controlling the
website where customers order goods — Amazon.com — even if those goods were sold
by 3rd-party merchants. Why would Amazon give that up?

The reasoning is straightforward: while Amazon has had Aggregator
characteristics, the company’s business model and differentiation has always
been rooted in the real world, which, by extension, means it is not an
Aggregator at all. I noted in 2017’s Defining Aggregators that Aggregators
benefit from zero marginal costs, which only describes a certain set of digital
businesses like Google and Facebook:

> Companies traditionally have had to incur (up to) three types of marginal
> costs when it comes to serving users/customers directly.
> 
>  * The cost of goods sold (COGS), that is, the cost of producing an item or
>    providing a service
>  * Distribution costs, that is the cost of getting an item to the customer
>    (usually via retail) or facilitating the provision of a service (usually
>    via real estate)
>  * Transaction costs, that is the cost of executing a transaction for a good
>    or service, providing customer service, etc.
> 
> Aggregators incur none of these costs:
> 
>  * The goods “sold” by an Aggregator are digital and thus have zero marginal
>    costs (they may, of course, have significant fixed costs)
>  * These digital goods are delivered via the Internet, which results in zero
>    distribution costs
>  * Transactions are handled automatically through automatic account
>    management, credit card payments, etc.
> 
> This characteristic means that businesses like Apple hardware and Amazon’s
> traditional retail operations are not Aggregators; both bear significant costs
> in serving the marginal customer (and, in the case of Amazon in particular,
> have achieved such scale that the service’s relative cost of distribution is
> actually a moat).

Amazon’s control of demand has been — and will continue to be — a tremendous
advantage; Amazon not only has power over its suppliers, but it also gets all of
the relevant data from consumers, which it can feed into a self-contained ad
platform that is untouched by regulation from either governments or Apple.

At the same time, limiting a business to customer touchpoints that you control
means limiting your overall addressable market. This may not matter in markets
where there are network effects (which means you appeal to everyone) and you are
an Aggregator dealing with zero marginal costs (and thus can realistically cover
every consumer); in the case of e-commerce, though, Amazon will never be the
only option, particularly given The Anti-Amazon Alliance working hard to reach
consumers.

A core part of the Anti-Amazon Alliance are companies that have invested in
brands that attract customers on their own; these companies don’t need to be on
Amazon fighting to be the answer to generic search terms, but can rather drive
customers to their own Shopify-powered websites both organically and via paid
advertising (Facebook is a huge player in the Anti-Amazon Alliance). Still,
every customer that visits these websites has an Amazon-driven expectation in
terms of shipping; Shippo CEO Laura Behrens Wu told me in a Stratechery
interview:

> Consumers have those expectations from Amazon that shipping should be free, it
> should be two days, and whatever those are expectations are, returns should be
> free. That is still carried over when I’m buying on this branded website. If
> the expectations are not met, consumers decide to buy somewhere else…Merchants
> are constantly trying to play catch up, whatever Amazon is doing they need to
> follow suit.

Now Amazon has — or soon will have, in the case of Shopify-only merchants — a
solution: the best way to get an Amazon-like shipping experience is to ship via
Amazon. And, in contrast to the crappy Webstore product, you can keep using
Shopify and its ecosystem for your website. Amazon may have given away business
to Shopify in 2015, but that doesn’t much matter if said business ends up being
a commoditized complement to Amazon’s true differentiation in logistics. That
business, thanks to the sheer expense necessary to build it out, has a nearly
impregnable moat that is not only attractive to all of the businesses competing
to be consumer touchpoints — thus increasing Amazon’s addressable market — but
is also one that sees its moat deepen the larger it becomes.

SHOPIFY’S PREDICAMENT AND AMAZON’S OPPORTUNITY

The reason this announcement is so damaging to Shopify goes back to the
transformation in the company’s revenue I charted above: Amazon’s shipping
solution requires the customer to pay with Amazon; I love Shop Pay’s checkout
process, but it’s not as if I don’t have an Amazon account with all of my
relevant details already included, and I absolutely trust Amazon’s shipping more
than I do whatever option some Shopify merchant offers me. If I had a choice I’m
taking the Amazon option every time.

Granted, I may not be representative; I’m a bit of a special case given where I
live. What is worth noting, though, is that every transaction that Amazon
processes is one not processed by Shopify, which again, is the company’s primary
revenue driver. Moreover, the more volume that Amazon processes, the more
difficult it will be for Shopify to get their own shipping solution to scale.
This endangers the company’s current major initiative.

That is why I think the company needs to think more deeply than ever about
advertising: the implication of Amazon being willing to be a services provider
and not necessarily an Aggregator is that Amazon is surrendering some number of
customer touchpoints to competitors; to put it another way, Amazon is actually
making competitive customer touchpoints better — touchpoints that Shopify
controls. Shopify ought to leverage that control.

That noted, there is a potential wrench in this plan: if Shopify doesn’t own
payment processing, will they have sufficient data to build a competitive
conversion-data-driven advertising product? Amazon — and Apple — would likely
argue that that data is Amazon’s, but the merchant will obviously know what is
going on (by the same token, will Amazon be able to tie this off-platform
conversion data back to its own advertising product? It’s not clear what would
stop them).

Shopify has two additional saving graces:

 * First, the fact that Amazon will be able to collect data is a big reason for
   many merchants not to use Amazon’s new offering. Shopify’s offering will
   always be differentiated in this regard.
 * Second, as the announcement noted, this is going to take Amazon a year or two
   to fully roll out, and lots of stuff can change in the meantime.

Moreover, while AWS has always been excellent at serving external customers
— which it did before Amazon.com ever actually moved over — Amazon’s
off-Amazon.com merchant offerings have never been particularly successful
(including the aforementioned Webstores).

With that in mind, I think it’s meaningful that “Buy With Prime” is the first
major initiative of new CEO Andy Jassy’s regime; I don’t think it’s an accident
that it is so clearly inspired by AWS. AWS’s strength is its focus on
infrastructure at scale; successfully moving e-commerce beyond aggregation to
the same type of service business model would put his stamp on the company in a
meaningful way, and, contra that quote in Bloomberg Businessweek, mark Jassy as
nobody’s fool.


POSTS NAVIGATION

Older Posts
Search for:




BY BEN THOMPSON

 * About
 * Dithering
 * Exponent


THE DAILY UPDATE

About The Daily Update
Subscribe: Monthly | Annual
Member Forum


FOLLOW

Create an account to receive
Weekly Updates via
Email, Podcast, or RSS


EXPLORE STRATECHERY

 * Concepts
 * Companies
 * Topics


ARCHIVES

 * Articles
 * Daily Updates
 * Years in Review


ACCOUNT

 * Member
 * Delivery Preferences
 * Manage Account
 * Sign Out

 * Log In
 * Sign Up

Loading


SUPPORT

Please email support@stratechery.com
On the business, strategy, and impact of technology. © Stratechery LLC 2022 |
Terms of Service | Privacy Policy